Methodology for Current Account and Exchange Rate Assessments
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
O C C A S I O N A L PA P E R 209 209 209 Methodology for Current Account and Exchange Rate Assessments Methodology for Current Account and Exchange Rate Assessments Peter Isard, Hamid Faruqee, G. Russell Kincaid, and Martin Fetherston INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND Methodology for Current Account and Washington DC 2001 Exchange Rate Assessments 2001 ISBN 1-58906-081-4
O C C A S I O N A L PA P E R 209 Methodology for Current Account and Exchange Rate Assessments Peter Isard, Hamid Faruqee, G. Russell Kincaid, and Martin Fetherston INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND Washington DC 2001
© 2001 International Monetary Fund Production: IMF Graphics Section Figures: Sanaa Elaroussi Typesetting: Alicia Etchebarne-Bourdin Cataloging-in-Publication Data Methodology for current account and exchange rate assessments/Peter Isard . . . [et al.]—Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund, 2001. p. cm.—(Occasional paper, 0251-6365); 209 Includes bibliographical references ISBN 1-58906-081-4 1. Foreign exchange rates. 2. Balance of payments. 3. International Mone- tary Fund. I. Isard, Peter. II. International Monetary Fund. III. Occasional paper (International Monetary Fund); no. 209 HG3821.M35 2001 Price: US$20.00 (US$17.50 to full-time faculty members and students at universities and colleges) Please send orders to: International Monetary Fund, Publication Services 700 19th Street, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20431, U.S.A. Tel.: (202) 623-7430 Telefax: (202) 623-7201 E-mail: publications@imf.org Internet: http://www.imf.org recycled paper
Contents Preface v I Overview 1 II A Methodology for Assessments of Industrial Countries 3 Background and Caveats 3 Macroeconomic Balance Assessments 6 Other Relevant Considerations and Summary Judgments 16 Applications in IMF Surveillance 17 III A Methodology for Assessments of Emerging Market Economies 19 Points of Departure 19 Criteria for Assessing Sustainability 20 IV Summary and Concluding Comments 22 Appendixes I Alternative Methodologies for Assessing Equilibrium Exchange Rates 24 II A Model of Current Account Adjustment and Benchmark Comparators for the WEO Projections 27 III The Saving-Investment Model for Industrial Countries 29 IV An Econometric Study of Saving-Investment Behavior in Developing Economies 32 References 35 Tables 1. Illustrative Assessments 15 2. Saving-Investment Equation for Industrial Countries 30 3. Results of Panel Regressions 33 Figures 1. Selected Industrial Countries: Nominal and Real Effective Exchange Rates, January 1980–January 2001 2 2. Exchange Rate Changes Versus Inflation Differentials Over Different Time Intervals 4 3. Real Exchange Rates Between the United Kingdom and Germany, 1970–2000 5 4. Medium-Run Fundamentals 8 5. Saving-Investment Norms, 1990–2006 12 iii
CONTENTS The following symbols have been used throughout this paper: . . . to indicate that data are not available; — to indicate that the figure is zero or less than half the final digit shown, or that the item does not exist; – between years or months (e.g., 2000–01 or January–June) to indicate the years or months covered, including the beginning and ending years or months; / between years (e.g., 2000/01) to indicate a fiscal (financial) year. “Billion” means a thousand million. Minor discrepancies between constituent figures and totals are due to rounding. The term “country,” as used in this paper, does not in all cases refer to a territorial entity that is a state as understood by international law and practice; the term also covers some territorial entities that are not states, but for which statistical data are maintained and provided interna- tionally on a separate and independent basis. iv
Preface In carrying out its bilateral and multilateral surveillance responsibilities, the IMF needs to make judgments about the consistency between prevailing exchange rates and medium-run fundamentals. This paper discusses the methodologies used by the IMF staff, pointing to conceptual and empirical limitations and to various issues that arise in interpreting the assessments. These methodologies will continue to evolve over time in response to efforts to strengthen the existing framework. Among the IMF staff, much of the responsibility for shaping consensus on method- ology and conducting exchange rate assessments has been assigned to the interdepart- mental Coordinating Group on Exchange Rate Issues (CGER). CGER was established in 1995 under the cochairmanship of representatives from the Policy Development and Review Department and the Research Department, and with active participation of the IMF’s area departments. The authors of this paper have each played a major role in CGER’s work. Russell Kincaid held the Policy Development and Review Department cochair position from fall 1998 to spring 2001, Martin Fetherston is currently the Pol- icy Development and Review Department cochair, Peter Isard has been cochair for the Research Department, and Hamid Faruqee has made central contributions to the methodological framework while also facilitating the assessment exercises in numer- ous ways. The general direction of CGER’s analytical work has been guided mainly by Stanley Fischer, the First Deputy Managing Director of the IMF (through August 2001), Michael Mussa, the Economic Counsellor and Director of the Research Depart- ment (through July 2001), and Jack Boorman, Counsellor and Director of the Policy Development and Review Department (through November 2001). The paper has benefited from discussion at an IMF Executive Board seminar in June 2001. The authors are also grateful for numerous comments and suggestions received from Thomas Krueger and other colleagues on the IMF staff, to Susanna Mursula and Sarma Jayanthi for research assistance, and to Victoria Ashiru and Dawn Heaney for preparing the manuscript. Esha Ray of the External Relations Department edited the manuscript and coordinated production of the publication. The opinions expressed in the paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the IMF or its Executive Directors. v
I Overview urveillance over the exchange rate policies of its change rates among major currencies during recent S member countries is a central responsibility of the International Monetary Fund. In late 1994, the decades. As illustrated by Figure 1, both the nominal and real effective (weighted-average) exchange rates IMF staff took a step toward making its surveillance of major currencies have frequently exhibited pro- more effective by initiating more extensive and sys- longed movements in one direction followed by pro- tematic assessments of the current account positions nounced reversals. One case in point is the dramatic and exchange rates of the major industrial countries, rise of the U.S. dollar during the first half of the incorporating both the perspectives of the IMF’s area 1980s, followed by an equally large drop between departments and calculations derived from a multi- early 1985 and early 1987. The Japanese yen and the lateral framework implemented by the IMF Re- pound sterling have also been pushed to sharply ap- search Department. In 1995, an interdepartmental preciated and depreciated levels a number of times working group, the Coordinating Group on Ex- over the past two decades, and similar wide variation change Rate Issues (CGER), was established to is evident for weighted-average exchange rates of strengthen and extend this work, and to provide a the deutsche mark against the currencies of countries greater degree of discipline and consistency in the outside the euro area. staff’s judgments about exchange rates. CGER’s Economists have achieved reasonable success in general approach for assessing the current accounts developing an understanding of the relationships be- and exchange rates of the major industrial countries tween exchange rates and macroeconomic funda- was reviewed by the IMF’s Executive Board in Oc- mentals over the medium run and, hence, of the tober 1997, and a description of the methodology trends in exchange rates over time. In particular, was subsequently made public.1 trends in nominal exchange rates tend to reflect in- This paper reports further on CGER’s work, as flation differentials over the medium run, and real reviewed by the IMF’s Executive Board in June exchange rates tend to gravitate toward levels at 2001. It provides perspectives on alternative frame- which the associated current account imbalances are works for assessing exchange rates and the rationale fairly moderate in size and consistent with factors for CGER’s general approach (Section II and Ap- that influence the relative saving and investment po- pendix I); it updates the description of the method- sitions of different countries over the medium run. It ology for assessing the current accounts and ex- has also been demonstrated formally that the short- change rates of industrial countries, pointing to the run behavior of exchange rates includes a large un- relative strengths and weaknesses of CGER’s ana- predictable component. Although a consensus has lytic framework and the judgments involved in de- emerged on partial explanations for some of the riving and interpreting the quantitative assessments large deviations of currency values from their (Section II and Appendixes II and III); it describes medium-run trends, such as the impact of the shift in some initial efforts to develop a separate methodol- the U.S. policy mix in pushing the dollar higher in ogy for assessing the current account positions of 1980–82, for the most part changes in macroeco- emerging market economies (Section III and Ap- nomic fundamentals have not provided convincing pendix IV); and it concludes with a brief summary and generally accepted explanations for the wide (Section IV). The focus of this paper is on method- swings in exchange rates. This has contributed to the ology and interpretive issues, rather than on numeri- view that market exchange rates sometimes become cal assessments. substantially misaligned with medium-run macro- CGER’s work on industrial countries is motivated economic fundamentals. by the wide fluctuations that have occurred in ex- Wide swings in real exchange rates have major effects on countries’ competitiveness, which can have significant implications for the growth and 1Isard and Faruqee (1998). composition of economic activity and 1
I OVERVIEW Figure 1. Selected Industrial Countries: Nominal and Real Effective Ex- change Rates, January 1980–January 20011 (1990=100; logarithmic scale) 200 200 United States Japan 175 175 150 150 125 125 Real 100 100 Real Nominal 75 75 Nominal 50 50 1980 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 2000 1980 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 2000 200 200 Germany United Kingdom 175 175 150 150 Nominal 125 125 Real2 100 100 Real 75 75 Nominal2 50 50 1980 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 2000 1980 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 2000 Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics. 1Real effective exchange rates are based on consumer price indices. Increases correspond to appreciations. 2Weighted averages against trading partners outside the euro area. employment.2 Moreover, the potential for substan- misalignments should be communicated in a timely tial nominal and real effects of large exchange rate and confidential manner to the authorities concerned. changes complicates the task of monetary policy, In light of the considerable difficulties in estimating sometimes adding significantly to the difficulties of equilibrium exchange rates, the IMF has generally not keeping economies expanding at close to full po- taken a public posture on exchange rate misalign- tential and with low inflation. Accordingly, the be- ments. On a number of occasions, however, CGER’s havior of exchange rates is a relevant concern for assessments have provided a basis for the staff and policymakers. In making policy decisions, it can be management to express qualitative judgments about important to assess by how much prevailing ex- exchange rates among the major currencies, both in change rates deviate from the levels that are consis- the context of the World Economic Outlook (WEO) tent with medium-run fundamentals—or, equiva- and in meetings of the Group of Seven and other in- lently, the levels toward which exchange rates seem ternational fora. The assessments have also been em- likely to gravitate over time. ployed by the IMF’s area departments in their dia- In providing guidance to IMF staff, the Executive logues with national authorities during Article IV Board has stressed that the IMF’s views on possible consultations with industrial countries, and in some cases the assessments for individual countries have 2In addition, sharp currency appreciations often give rise to po- appeared in published staff reports. CGER revisits its litical pressures to protect exchange-rate-sensitive sectors of the assessments semiannually in association with the up- economy from foreign competition. dating of the WEO projections. 2
II A Methodology for Assessments of Industrial Countries Background and Caveats Partly for that reason, most methodologies for defin- ing equilibrium exchange rates have relied on models The quantification of equilibrium exchange rates of behavior over a medium- or long-run horizon.6 is a somewhat murky area of economics. Conceptual One traditional methodology for defining equilib- frameworks typically rely on strong simplifying as- rium exchange rates is the purchasing power parity sumptions, and the empirical support for different (PPP) approach, which hypothesizes that the nominal approaches is mixed. From a policymaking perspec- exchange rate between any two currencies should re- tive, however, such exercises are important: the IMF flect closely the relative purchasing powers of the two cannot effectively exercise its surveillance responsi- monetary units, as indicated by national price levels.7 bilities without forming views about possible mis- It is commonly expressed as a hypothesis that, over a alignments of exchange rates and considering the given period of time, the percentage change in the risks of sudden and sharp corrections of currency nominal exchange rate between any two currencies misalignments. will equal the difference between the percentage Success in explaining the behavior of exchange changes in the price levels of the two corresponding rates—and, hence, in providing meaningful empirical countries—or, equivalently, that the real exchange support for methodologies of assessing equilibrium rate between the two currencies remains constant. exchange rates in terms of economic fundamentals— Although PPP has been discredited as a hypothesis depends importantly on time horizons. Based largely about the relationship between exchange rates and na- on research that flourished during the 1970s and early tional price levels in the short run,8 the econometric 1980s, economists have concluded that models of the evidence is much more favorable to PPP as a hypothe- links between currency values and economic funda- sis about medium-run or long-run behavior.9 This is mentals perform little if any better than random walks illustrated by Figure 2. Changes in nominal exchange in predicting the behavior of exchange rates in the short run.3 Furthermore, from surveys of commercial 6The dramatic changes that have occurred in the size of finan- banks and other private financial institutions that ac- cial asset holdings, and in the amounts of these holdings that can tively participate in exchange markets, policymakers be moved rapidly between countries and/or currencies, have led have learned that market participants condition their some to suggest that the short-run behavior of exchange rates can short-run trading strategies to a large extent on “tech- be explained in terms of capital flows and that current account nical analysis” of very recent trends or other patterns flows have a relatively minor influence. This view can be mis- in the observed behavior of exchange rates, although leading in two senses. First, although exchange rate movements and capital flows may be closely associated in the short run, it they regard fundamentals as much more important would be misleading to regard capital flows as more than a proxi- than technical analysis in their long-term decision mate cause of exchange rate movements; a deeper understanding making.4 These perspectives discredit the notion that of the short-run behavior of exchange rates would require an un- exchange rates should be expected to adjust, in the derstanding of the factors that drive capital flows. Second, be- cause the capital account and current account are linked by the short run, to fundamentals-based equilibrium levels.5 balance of payments identity, it would be misleading to suggest that the behavior of exchange rates is more closely related to the capital account than to the current account. 3 Meese and Rogoff (1983a, 1983b, 1988). Numerous at- 7The term purchasing power parity was coined in the early tempts to overturn the Meese-Rogoff results have failed; see twentieth century by Cassel (1918, 1922). Rogoff (1999) and the survey by Frankel and Rose (1995). 8Whether one looks at consumer price indices, GDP deflators, Moreover, as emphasized by Flood and Rose (1999), the short- wholesale price indices, unit labor costs, or export price indices, run volatility of exchange rates far exceeds the volatility of there is considerable month-to-month and quarter-to-quarter vari- macroeconomic fundamentals. ation in the associated measures of real exchange rates. Hyperin- 4Group of Ten Deputies (1993). flations provide exceptional circumstances in which PPP has not 5Economists have also had limited success in finding fundamen- been discredited as a description of short-run behavior. tals-based explanations for the short-run behavior of the prices of 9See Breuer (1994), Isard (1995), Froot and Rogoff (1995), and assets other than foreign exchange—for example, equity prices. Rogoff (1996) for summary discussions. 3
II A METHODOLOGY FOR ASSESSMENTS OF INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES Figure 2. Exchange Rate Changes Versus Inflation Differentials Over Dif- ferent Time Intervals1 50 50 40 1-Year Intervals 40 6-Year Intervals 30 30 20 20 10 10 0 0 –10 –10 –20 –20 –30 –30 –40 –40 –50 –50–50 –40 –30 –20 –10 0 10 20 30 40 50 –50 –40 –30 –20 –10 0 10 20 30 40 50 50 50 40 12-Year Intervals 40 24-Year Intervals 30 30 20 20 10 10 0 0 –10 –10 –20 –20 –30 –30 –40 –40 –50 –50 –50 –40 –30 –20 –10 0 10 20 30 40 50 –50 –40 –30 –20 –10 0 10 20 30 40 50 1Based on Flood and Taylor (1996). The plots are constructed from annual average data on the nominal ex- change rates of 20 industrial country currencies versus the U.S. dollar, along with corresponding consumer price indices, for the period 1976–2000. Changes in exchange rates are measured along the horizontal axes; changes in CPIs along the vertical axes.The first panel plots 480 one-year changes (24 for each country); the second plots 80 nonoverlapping six-year changes (at annual rates) corresponding to the periods 1976–82, 1982–88, 1988–94, and 1994–2000; and so forth. rates are measured along the horizontal axis, inflation by how much, to adjust nominal exchange rates. differentials are measured along the vertical axis, and Such use of the PPP formula to calculate an appro- the diagonal 45 degree line represents the set of points priate or “equilibrium” level for the nominal ex- that are consistent with the PPP hypothesis. The fig- change rate requires a decision about the type of ure shows that PPP becomes a much more respectable price (or cost) index on which the calculations are to hypothesis as the time horizon is lengthened, and be based, as well as an assumption about the equilib- that—at least over the past quarter century—the long- rium level of the real exchange rate. The latter is run PPP hypothesis fits the data for industrial coun- generally taken to be the observed level of the real tries remarkably well.10 exchange rate during some selected base year, or the Policymakers have relied on the PPP formula on average level of the real exchange rate over an ex- various occasions to help them decide whether, and tended period of time. Sensitivity to the price (or cost) measure and base period that are chosen limits the usefulness of PPP as 10The fit is not as close for the developing countries or for the a normative approach. Figure 3 plots five measures industrial countries over the previous quarter century. Indeed, as of the real exchange rate between the pound sterling elaborated in the discussion of the Balassa-Samuelson hypothesis in Appendix I, there is empirical evidence of systematic devia- and the deutsche mark from 1970 through 2000. tions from PPP. Each of the measures suggests that the pound was 4
Background and Caveats Figure 3. Real Exchange Rates Between the United Kingdom and Ger- many, 1970–2000 (1970=100) Based on consumer price indices Based on GDP deflators Average, 1990–2000 Average, 1990–2000 Average, 1970–2000 Average, 1970–2000 140 140 120 120 100 100 80 80 60 60 1970 73 76 79 82 85 88 91 94 97 2000 1970 73 76 79 82 85 88 91 94 97 2000 Based on wholesale price indices Based on normalized unit labor costs Average, 1990–2000 Average, 1990–2000 Average, 1970–2000 Average, 1970–2000 140 140 120 120 100 100 80 80 60 60 1970 73 76 79 82 85 88 91 94 97 2000 1970 73 76 79 82 85 88 91 94 97 2000 Based on export price indices Average, 1990–2000 Average, 1970–2000 140 120 100 80 60 1970 73 76 79 82 85 88 91 94 97 2000 Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff calculations. stronger than its equilibrium rate (proxied by long- Given the limitations of the PPP hypothesis as a term averages) against the deutsche mark (hence, the normative approach, economists have been attracted euro) in 2000; but the magnitude of the estimated to other methodologies for assessing exchange rates. deviation from equilibrium ranges from 10 percent CGER relies heavily on the macroeconomic balance to 40 percent, depending on the type of price or cost approach, which makes quantitative assessments of index used and the averaging period chosen. exchange rates that are consistent with “appropriate” 5
II A METHODOLOGY FOR ASSESSMENTS OF INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES current account positions (external balance) when different places. Such imprecision provides the ratio- economies are operating at potential output (internal nale for generating assessments with both the macro- balance). Other approaches include an extended PPP economic balance framework and a PPP approach, methodology that takes account of Balassa-Samuel- and for characterizing CGER’s summary assessments son effects, estimated reduced-form models of ex- as approximations or ranges that involve a significant change rate behavior, and the approach of relying on element of judgment. general equilibrium frameworks. Appendix I outlines A further important caveat is that large deviations these alternative approaches and why CGER has cho- of exchange rates from their medium-run equilibrium sen not to rely on them. levels (even if these could be estimated precisely) do Key features of the macroeconomic balance ap- not necessarily represent currency misalignments. In proach have been prominent in calculations by the some cases, such deviations may reflect short-term IMF staff since at least as far back as 1967, when cyclical factors rather than medium-run disequilibria. views were developed about the appropriate size of Moreover, regardless of their cause, deviations of ex- the prospective devaluation of sterling.11 As refined change rates from medium-run equilibrium can some- by the IMF staff during the 1970s and early 1980s,12 times be helpful from a short-run perspective; in par- and also used by Williamson (1985) and others in ticular, an appreciated currency can help cool an their early work on “fundamental equilibrium ex- overheated economy, just as a depreciated currency change rates” (FEERs), the macroeconomic balance can help reinvigorate a weak one. Furthermore, quite approach was rooted in the balance of payments iden- apart from cyclical considerations, deviations of ex- tity. In particular, these applications tended to define change rates from medium-run equilibrium some- external balance in terms of “balanced” or “normal” times reflect a need for policy adjustment rather than or “target” or “underlying” capital flows, and then es- an indication that markets are wrong. timated the levels of real exchange rates that would Two related points should be kept in mind when equate current account balances—at positions of in- interpreting CGER’s assessments. First, the assess- ternal balance—to these notions of equilibrium capi- ment that a currency is substantially stronger or tal flows. By contrast, CGER applications, as elabo- weaker than its medium-run equilibrium level does rated below, are rooted in the national income not necessarily imply a high probability of a sudden accounting identity that links the current account to and sharp correction. Consequently, it is difficult to the saving-investment balance. While the two identi- evaluate the assessments on the basis of their track ties are closely related, the shift in emphasis has been record in anticipating exchange rate movements. The in the direction of relying less on ad hoc judgments failure of the U.S. dollar to weaken significantly about equilibrium capital flows, which are difficult to since early 1997, when CGER began to assess it as make in an environment of high and rising capital mo- substantially stronger than its medium-run equilib- bility, and more on models of the behavior of the sav- rium level, can be interpreted as either a persistent ing-investment balance over the medium run.13 error in CGER’s analysis or an implication of the It is important to recognize at the outset that possibility that deviations from medium-run equilib- CGER’s analysis is subject to considerable limitations rium can be persistent. Second, there is no general in generating definitive estimates and to various answer to the question of whether policy actions caveats in interpreting the assessments. A key limita- should be taken when exchange rates appear to devi- tion is that the quantitative assessments are inherently ate substantially from their medium-run equilibrium imprecise. In general, economists do not have the values. The latter issue needs to be addressed on a conceptual basis or empirical methodology for gener- case-by-case basis in the context of a broader assess- ating precise estimates of the exchange rate levels that ment of macroeconomic circumstances. are consistent with medium-run macroeconomic fun- damentals. As will become evident below, impreci- sion enters CGER’s quantitative analysis in several Macroeconomic Balance Assessments As noted earlier, the macroeconomic balance 11See framework is based on the accounting identity that Polak (1995), who emphasizes the focus on external bal- ance and the use of elasticity calculations but does not mention links a country’s current account balance (CUR) to internal balance. The macroeconomic balance approach appar- the excess of domestic saving (S) over domestic in- ently began to take shape in the writings of Nurkse (1945) and vestment (I).14 Metzler (1951) and benefited from pathbreaking contributions by Meade (1951) and Swan (1963). 12Artus (1978) and Artus and Knight (1984). 14There are some definitional distinctions between national ac- 13See, for example, Knight and Masson (1988), Williamson counts concepts and balance of payments concepts that need to be (1994), Clark and others (1994), Debelle and Faruqee (1996), taken into account when applying the macroeconomic balance Isard and Faruqee (1998), and Faruqee, Isard, and Masson framework, especially with respect to the treatment of net factor (1999). income payments and transfers. 6
Macroeconomic Balance Assessments CUR = S – I. (1) neously, the underlying current account position with the medium-run equilibrium saving-investment bal- The current account balance is explicitly recognized ance. Although this calculation is made in a multilat- to depend on the real exchange rate, which influ- eral framework, it is broadly similar to estimating the ences the volumes and prices of exports and imports. difference between R1 and R*, where R* corresponds A complicating feature is that the effects of changes to the medium-run equilibrium exchange rate at in the exchange rate on CUR usually take some time which the UCUR and S-I lines intersect. to materialize fully. CUR also depends on the levels The methodology also involves applications of of domestic and foreign aggregate demand (or other judgment, both in implementing each of the steps in measures of economic activity) and various other the macroeconomic balance approach and in consid- factors. ering whether and how much to adjust the resulting The broad outline of CGER’s approach remains un- macroeconomic balance assessments from PPP per- changed from the overview presented in Isard and spectives and other information that may be relevant. Faruqee (1998) and is recapitulated here for conve- Additional judgment is required in deciding whether nience. The first step in applying the framework is to the final quantitative assessments imply a need for estimate each country’s underlying current account policy adjustment in the near term or point to signif- position, which is the relevant measure of CUR for as- icant risks for the macroeconomic outlook. sessing exchange rates from a medium-run perspec- tive. The underlying current account is defined as the value of CUR that would emerge at prevailing ex- Underlying Current Account Positions change rates if all countries were producing at their CGER has focused on two approaches to generat- potential output levels and the lagged effects of past ing estimates of underlying current account positions. exchange rate changes had been fully realized. Under One approach, developed by the IMF’s Research De- normal assumptions, a country’s underlying current partment (RES), is based on a standard trade model account position will be inversely related to the pre- that has a relatively simple structure and employs vailing level of its real exchange rate, as depicted by common equation specifications and parameter values the negatively sloped line labeled UCUR in Figure 4; across countries (see Appendix II). The model implic- that is, a decline (or depreciation) in the real exchange itly treats all current account outflows (inflows) as rate will normally improve the underlying current ac- merchandise exports (imports); treats goods produced count. If the real exchange rate was R1, the first step in in different countries as imperfect substitutes;16 as- the macroeconomic balance approach would identify sumes that export (import) volumes depend on both the underlying current account position as UCUR1. the level of foreign (domestic) activity and the current The second step is to derive an estimate of each and lagged values of the real effective exchange rate; country’s equilibrium saving-investment position, and assumes that exchange rate changes are fully which is interpreted as a balance that can be re- passed through into import prices, with no effect on garded as “normal” from a medium-run perspective. (domestic-currency-denominated) export prices. The Such estimates focus on the right-hand side of equa- model-based estimates of underlying current accounts tion (1) and also assume that countries are operating have the positive attributes of global consistency and at potential output. In Figure 4, the equilibrium sav- transparency, but the aggregation of non-oil trade, oil ing-investment balance is assumed to be indepen- trade, and other current account items (investment in- dent of the real exchange rate,15 as depicted by the come flows and transfers) and the lack of country- vertical S-I line. specific detail are disadvantages. The third step is to calculate how much real ex- A second approach is based on the current account change rates would have to change, other things being projections generated by the IMF’s country experts in equal, to be consistent with medium-run fundamen- connection with the World Economic Outlook exer- tals—that is, to equilibrate, for each country simulta- 15This simplifying assumption is consistent with the fact that 16As an alternative to treating the goods of different countries most empirically estimated reduced-form models of industrial as imperfect substitutes, which is the standard approach in mod- country saving and investment behavior do not include the ex- els used for projecting trade volumes empirically, some concep- change rate among the main determinants. As elaborated below, it tual models distinguish between tradable and nontradable goods, is also associated with an assumption that the industrial countries assume that tradable goods are homogeneous across countries, have perfect access to international capital markets (apart from and model current account adjustment as a process of shifting the any time-invariant interest rate premia). A more complete macro- balance between each country’s production and absorption of economic framework could recognize that exchange rates may in- tradable goods; see, for example, Dooley and Isard (1987) and fluence saving and investment through their effects on the terms Obstfeld and Rogoff (2000). Attempts to apply the latter approach of trade, the profitability of the traded-goods sector (or subsectors empirically are typically constrained by the paucity of data that susceptible to “Dutch disease”), the level of potential output, and adequately decompose production and absorption into their trad- the distribution of income. able and nontradable components. 7
II A METHODOLOGY FOR ASSESSMENTS OF INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES Figure 4. Medium-Run Fundamentals Real effective exchange rate S-I Equilibrium saving-investment balance R1 R* Underlying current account balance UCUR Current account 0 Deficit UCUR1 Surplus cise. For industrial countries (and most other coun- CGER has chosen to rely primarily on the WEO tries), the WEO projections are conditional on un- projections as estimates of underlying current ac- changed real exchange rates. Moreover, the projec- count positions. To avoid relying uncritically on the tions for the final year in the five-year WEO horizon WEO projections, however, it has disciplined its as- assume that economies are operating at potential out- sessments by generating alternative estimates of un- put and, in that sense, can be interpreted as estimates derlying current account positions from the globally of underlying current account positions. These projec- consistent RES model and taking those estimates tions have the advantage of incorporating the country- into account when shaping its summary judgments specific knowledge (including that from models and on exchange rates. It has also continued to use the projections of national authorities) and judgments of RES model in the third step of the CGER process the IMF’s area department staff. A disadvantage is (see below) for calculating the changes in real ex- that the separate projections for individual countries change rates that would be needed to make the un- may lack global consistency;17 indeed, at the time of derlying current account balances consistent with CGER’s semiannual assessment in March 2001, the medium-run equilibrium levels of saving-investment staff’s WEO projections summed to a global current balances. account deficit of 1 percent of projected 2006 world To strengthen the assessment process, the staff has GDP, compared with a global deficit in 2000 of about recently begun to develop benchmarks that can be 0.6 percent of GDP. This global inconsistency, which used as comparators for the individual components the WEO forecasts appear to share with most other of the WEO projections (see Appendix II). The de- forecasts, presents a problem for the CGER exercise, velopment of these benchmarks amounts, in effect, as discussed in more detail below. to an effort to construct an improved version of the RES model that disaggregates the current account 17For major industrial countries, the WEO projections are gen- into different components and employs a globally erated to a large extent from formal models, but the structures of consistent and common (across countries) frame- these models differ across countries. work for modeling each component. 8
Macroeconomic Balance Assessments The benchmarks are not intended as an alterna- norms to structural fiscal positions and cyclically ad- tive set of projections. The simple analytic models justed levels of relative per capita incomes, since the on which they are based, while having the impor- calculations are based on projections at the end of tant property of global consistency, do not take ac- the WEO horizon, where output gaps are zero. Third, count of country-specific factors. Moreover, history the structural fiscal positions that enter the S-I norms reveals considerable variation over time in ob- do not necessarily correspond to “desirable” fiscal served outcomes relative to benchmark calculations balances; nor should connotations of desirability be for individual countries. Nevertheless, the bench- attached to the equilibrium or “historically normal” marks provide CGER with a consistent and disci- S-I balances. plined approach for considering the possible direc- As elaborated in Appendix III, the long-run rela- tions of bias in estimates of underlying current tionship described by equation (2) is derived from a account balances based on the WEO projections model that takes account of cyclical variables, but and, accordingly, in the corresponding assessments country-specific interest rates play no explicit role. of exchange rates. Accordingly, the present version of the S-I model ab- stracts from various factors that are relevant to capital Saving-Investment Norms flows and portfolio allocation decisions in a world in which claims on different countries are perceived to The basis for CGER’s estimates of equilibrium or offer different expected returns and to be subject to normal saving-investment balances, here referred to different risks.20 Future efforts to strengthen the S-I as S-I norms, is an estimated equation generated in model should attempt to capture the influence of such the Research Department. This aspect of the present factors, but hopes for major improvements in this CGER framework remains considerably oversimpli- area are dimmed by the fact that economists have not fied but can be viewed as a significant advance in yet had much success in empirical efforts to explain terms of global consistency.18 how such factors systematically influence the behav- The assumptions and derivation of the S-I model ior of country-specific interest rate premia. are described in Appendix III.19 Updated estimates The parameter estimates in equation (2) imply that for the period 1971–99 yield the following long-run a 1 percentage point of GDP increase in a country’s relationship: relative structural fiscal surplus improves its current account by 0.23 percentage points of GDP. Changes CUR = ci + 0.23 SUR + 0.11 YPCAP, (2) in fiscal positions are thus found to have “non-Ricar- where CUR is the current account (expressed as a dian” effects; that is, an increase in public saving is ratio to GDP), SUR is the fiscal surplus (as a ratio to not fully offset by a reduction in private saving.21 A GDP) relative to the industrial country average, 1 percent improvement in a country’s relative per YPCAP is income per capita relative to that of the capita income raises its saving-investment balance United States, and the ci are country-specific con- by 0.11 percentage points of GDP, consistent with stant terms. the view that higher-income countries tend to be Several points may be noted about the general larger (net) exporters of capital, other things being structure and interpretation of this equation. First, equal. The framework implicitly captures the coun- current account positions would not change if all tercyclical effects of monetary policy on the output countries were to reduce their fiscal positions gap, which is included in the estimated equation (see equiproportionately, or to experience the same rates Appendix III), but abstracts from any explicit influ- of per capita income growth. Second, the use of the ence of monetary policy on the medium-run behav- equation to estimate the medium-run equilibrium ior of S-I balances or real exchange rates.22 levels of saving-investment balances relates the S-I 20An implicit assumption is that each country can borrow or 18Polak (1995) points to the lack of agreed analytic procedures lend any amount of capital internationally (i.e., any shortfall or for modeling equilibrium current account positions as a major excess of domestic saving relative to domestic investment) at a weakness in the IMF’s applications of the macroeconomic bal- fixed premium above the world rate of interest. This assumption ance approach during the 1970s and 1980s. Prior to the estima- of perfect capital mobility may be an acceptable simplification tion of a model of saving-investment behavior over the medium for industrial countries but would be inappropriate for most other run, CGER’s macroeconomic balance assessments for the major economies. 21There is a long-standing debate on the economic implications currencies were based on ad hoc assumptions about equilibrium ratios of net foreign assets to GDP and associated equilibrium ra- of public deficits; see Barro (1989) and Bernheim (1989) for re- tios of current accounts to GDP. See Williamson and Mahar views of the Ricardian and neoclassical perspectives. 22To the extent that success in mitigating macroeconomic insta- (1998) for an alternative exercise in generating S-I norms. 19The original econometric estimates are described in Debelle bility tends to promote per capita income growth (and perhaps re- and Faruqee (1996) and Faruqee and Debelle (1998), and the con- duces the cost of servicing public debt) over the medium run, the ceptual framework is further elaborated in Masson (1998) and framework can be viewed to indirectly capture certain longer-run Faruqee, Isard, and Masson (1999). effects of monetary policy. 9
II A METHODOLOGY FOR ASSESSMENTS OF INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES The saving-investment model has been estimated historical average levels of the S-I norms, which with country-specific constant terms to capture the are determined by observed data. Moreover, to the effects of omitted variables that may influence the extent that moving to a more sophisticated model relative saving and investment rates of different significantly changed the calculated values of the countries. These constant terms capture, for exam- norms for the particular year on which the assess- ple, the fact that a relatively low S-I balance has ments were based (i.e., the final year of the WEO been historically normal for the United States, other horizon), discontinuities in the assessments could things being equal, consistent with a relatively low be avoided—where warranted in CGER’s judg- observed saving rate for the United States, and per- ment—by making adjustments to the country-spe- haps also indicating a relatively strong desire of non- cific constant terms. residents to accumulate claims on the United States. Figure 5 shows the S-I norms that are implied by Equation (2) is a reduced-form relationship and equation (2) for the period from 1990 through should be interpreted carefully. The relative struc- 2006. The estimates for 2001–06 reflect the WEO tural fiscal positions that appear on the right-hand projections of explanatory variables as of March side of the equation should not be regarded as exoge- 2001. The United States, the United Kingdom, nous; in addition to reflecting tax rates and expendi- Canada, Australia, and New Zealand are countries ture levels that might reasonably be treated as exoge- in which current accounts have on average been in nous, structural fiscal positions can be influenced deficit over the past three decades, which is re- substantially by factors that affect productivity flected in the deficit positions of their S-I norms. growth and the level of potential output. Accord- The other industrial counties are all estimated to ingly, changes over time in the relative importance have equilibrium S-I surpluses. In the cases of Aus- of such factors can make the reduced-form parame- tralia, New Zealand, and Canada, the historically ters sensitive to the sample period over which they normal deficits in their S-I balances presumably re- are estimated. It is also widely recognized that the flect the combined influence of relatively abundant effects of fiscal policy changes on the overall S-I natural-resource-based investment opportunities balance can depend (both in magnitude and in sign) and relatively sparse populations. The largest sur- on how the policy changes affect perceptions about plus norms are associated with Norway and debt sustainability and the outlook for macroeco- Switzerland, consistent with the effects on S-I bal- nomic growth. Further work to better capture the ef- ances of substantial oil wealth in the case of Nor- fects of fiscal policy changes on overall saving-in- way and a relatively large net foreign asset position vestment positions is an important direction for in the case of Switzerland.23 enriching the S-I model. The changes in the norms from one year to the next, Although equation (2) is highly simplified and as derived from equation (2), stem from changes in leaves considerable scope for improvement through the observed or projected levels of structural fiscal future research efforts, it provides a consistent way balances and potential output (cyclically adjusted in- of capturing the sensitivity of overall saving-invest- come) per capita. In the United States the gradual up- ment balances to relative fiscal positions, stages of ward trend (decline in the norm deficit) during the development (per capita incomes), and other un- 1990s mainly reflects an improvement in the public specified factors operating through the country- sector’s structural budget position. In Japan the time specific constant terms. It can be regarded as a for- mula for generating estimates of equilibrium medium-run current account positions by adjusting 23The norms reflect adjustments to the country-specific con- historical averages—as captured by the country- stant terms for Japan, Australia, Denmark, New Zealand, Norway, specific constant terms—to account for changes and Switzerland. In each case, the adjustment has raised the level over time in variables that one might reasonably of the curve shown in Figure 5 without affecting the time profile of the norm; the implicit counterpart of these adjustments is an in- expect to affect saving-investment balances. The crease in the size of the deficit norm for the developing countries. estimated model has served the important purpose For Japan, the norm has been adjusted upward to offset the influ- of providing a basis for pinning down a set of judg- ence on the estimated country-specific constant term of the ab- ments on equilibrium saving-investment balances normal component of investment during the bubble of the 1980s and maintaining a high degree of consistency in and early 1990s. For Norway, the norm has been judgmentally raised in light of the effects on national wealth and saving of the those judgments over time. Extensions of the general rise in oil prices since the historical sample period. For model that succeeded in capturing the influence of Switzerland, the norm has been judgmentally raised to better cap- additional explanatory variables would also result ture the implications of a relatively high net foreign asset posi- in different estimates of the country-specific con- tion. For Australia, Denmark, and New Zealand, the norms were judgmentally raised (to a higher surplus for Denmark and lower stant terms. Such extensions would affect the time deficits in the other two cases) to avoid discontinuities on the oc- profiles of the S-I norms as functions of the ex- casion of shifting the calculations to updated estimates of the S-I planatory variables, but they would not affect the equation. 10
Macroeconomic Balance Assessments profile of the norm reflects the widening of the rela- level—would probably not be altered substantially tive structural fiscal deficit24 and relatively slow by a more sophisticated explanation of the historical growth of potential output during the 1990s, along behavior of the S-I balance for the United States.28 with the projection for a gradual reduction in the structural fiscal deficit during the five years ahead. Multilateral Exchange Rate Calculations For the euro area, the norm has been constructed by aggregating estimates for the individual member Step three of the process calculates the direction countries, with an adjustment to account for tempo- and magnitude of the implied exchange rate changes rary effects of German unification in the early that, assuming no changes in policies or other vari- 1990s.25 For most of the other countries, except ables, would bring currency values into line with Switzerland, the variation in the norms primarily medium-term fundamentals. This section highlights arises from changes over time in relative structural fis- aspects of the analytical framework that are relevant cal balances. For Switzerland, the downward trend in for the interpretation of these calculations and also the norm mainly comes from the relatively slow describes the treatment of the global discrepancy. growth of potential output per capita. As noted above, the UCUR line in Figure 4 is neg- The simple structure of the equation used to calcu- atively sloped to reflect the presumption that a lower late the S-I norms is one of the reasons that CGER’s real effective exchange rate is associated with an im- assessments should be viewed as imprecise.26 This provement in the current account over the medium poses a challenge for IMF staff in continuing their term. In the logic of CGER’s WEO-based assess- efforts to generate improved econometric estimates ments, the position of the UCUR line is assumed to of S-I behavior for the industrial countries in general reflect the projected values of economic variables at and to take account of specific factors or structural the end of the five-year WEO horizon, when output changes that may have major influences on S-I be- is at potential and the lagged effects of past ex- havior in individual countries.27 It bears repeating, change rate changes have been realized. Thus, pro- however, that the general levels of the S-I norms re- jected changes in economic fundamentals, including flect the average historical values of the S-I balances effects of announced policy changes, are already re- and would probably not be affected substantially by flected in the position of the UCUR line. By con- more sophisticated explanations of the observed trast, any unanticipated changes in relevant eco- data. Thus, the main message that emerges from re- nomic variables over the WEO horizon, including cent CGER assessments—that the U.S. dollar is con- changes that arise from unanticipated policy actions, siderably stronger than its medium-run equilibrium would shift the position of the UCUR line. The vertical S-I line in Figure 4 shows the normal level of the saving-investment balance determined in 24The deterioration of Japan’s relative structural fiscal deficit step two. The line is vertical because the normal during the 1990s stems from both the substantial deterioration of level of the S-I balance (at potential output) is as- Japan’s own fiscal position and significant improvements in sumed not to depend on the exchange rate.29 Its posi- structural fiscal positions elsewhere. 25The panel data set used to estimate the S-I model included the tion, like that of the UCUR line, reflects the projec- members of the euro area as individual countries, partly in recogni- tions for relevant economic variables (in this case, tion of the separate status of their currencies during most of the per capita income levels and structural fiscal bal- sample period and also to provide more degrees of freedom. Aggre- ances) at the end of the medium-run WEO horizon. gate euro area variables were then constructed either by adding the Given the initial real exchange rate (R1) and under- variables for the individual member countries or as weighted aver- ages, as appropriate. (Weighted averages make sense for variables lying current account position (UCUR1), the amount expressed as ratios to GDP, including the country-specific constant of exchange rate adjustment that is needed to equili- terms in the equation that explains the S-I balance as a ratio to GDP.) For purposes of using the RES model to calculate the amounts that current accounts and exchange rates need to adjust to reach medium-run equilibrium levels (see below), intra-euro-area 28As elaborated in Appendix III, the estimates of the S-I model trade was removed from measures of euro area exports and im- were updated prior to the March 2001 assessment exercise, which ports. This makes the framework consistent with the assumption changed the 2006 value of the calculated S-I norm for the United that adjustments in euro exchange rates affect trade between the States to a deficit of 1.6 percentage points of GDP—an upward euro area and the rest of the world but do not affect trade among revision (in absolute value) of #/4 of 1 percentage point of GDP. members of the euro area. It also has the effect of treating the euro That reduced by about 10 percentage points the macroeconomic area in the aggregate as a less open economy than its individual balance calculation of the amount that the U.S. dollar would need member countries on average. to depreciate in multilateral terms to reach its medium-run equi- 26Such oversimplification limits the usefulness of the macroeco- librium level. nomic balance approach as a normative tool, just as the usefulness 29As noted earlier, this simplifying assumption could be re- of a PPP-based assessment for normative purposes is limited by laxed in principle (implying a nonvertical S-I line)—for example, sensitivity to the type of price index and averaging period chosen. to recognize the phenomenon of “Dutch disease.” However, the 27Krajnyák (2000) has developed a portfolio allocation model simplifying assumption is consistent with many other empirical of S-I behavior for Switzerland. models of saving and investment behavior. 11
II A METHODOLOGY FOR ASSESSMENTS OF INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES Figure 5. Saving-Investment Norms, 1990–2006 (In percent of GDP) 0 5 United States Japan –1 4 –2 3 –3 2 –41990 92 94 96 98 2000 02 04 06 1990 92 94 96 98 2000 02 04 06 1 3 1 Euro Area United Kingdom 2 0 1 –1 0 –2 –1 –3 1990 92 94 96 98 2000 02 04 06 1990 92 94 96 98 2000 02 04 06 0 Canada –1 –2 –3 –41990 92 94 96 98 2000 02 04 06 brate the underlying current account with the equilib- smaller percentage changes in their real exchange rium S-I balance depends on the slope of the UCUR rates, other things being equal, to achieve given line. The assumptions on which the calculations are changes in their trade volumes or underlying current based (see below) imply that the slope of the UCUR account positions (as shares of GDP). line depends on the openness of the economy. Coun- Unexpected changes in economic fundamentals— tries with relatively high ratios of exports and imports that is, deviations from the changes projected in the to GDP have relatively flat UCUR lines and require WEO—can shift the position of either the vertical 12
Macroeconomic Balance Assessments Figure 5 (concluded) 0 4 Australia Denmark –1 3 –2 2 –3 1 –41990 92 94 96 98 2000 02 04 06 1990 92 94 96 98 2000 02 04 06 0 –2 6 New Zealand Norway –3 5 –4 4 –5 3 –61990 92 94 96 98 2000 02 04 06 2 1990 92 94 96 98 2000 02 04 06 3 8 Sweden Switzerland 2 7 1 6 0 5 –11990 92 94 96 98 2000 02 04 06 1990 92 94 96 98 2000 02 04 06 4 Source: IMF staff estimates. S-I line or the negatively sloped UCUR line or both, equilibrium exchange rate will depend on the extent and can thereby alter the real effective exchange rate of the shift in the vertical S-I line, on the slope of the that is consistent with medium-run fundamentals. UCUR line, and on the extent of any shift in the For example, a greater-than-projected increase in UCUR line. By themselves, shifts in the position of (relative) per capita income or the (relative) struc- the UCUR line (due to unexpected changes in tural fiscal surplus will shift the S-I line in Figure 4 medium-run fundamentals that affect the current ac- to the right. The size of the implied change in the count through channels other than the real exchange 13
You can also read