Italy at the crossroads - CBS
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Italy at the crossroads By Svend E. Hougaard Jensen and Andrea Tafuro ∗ Concerns about the Italian economy appear to have evaporated under Draghi’s leadership. However, despite enjoying a reasonably solid leadership at the moment, Italy still remains the most fragile economy among developed countries, with a huge public debt and low growth prospects. The recent Spring Forecast from the European Commission helps us define the perimeter of this fragility - namely, public debt. Currently at the order €2,500 billion, its share of GDP is set to increase to 159.8% this year, falling only slightly in 2022 to 156.6%. Three elements can help secure the medium-term sustainability of such a large debt. First, a quick recovery after the pandemic, which the Commission estimates to be 4.2% and 4.4% in 2021-2022; second, the maintenance of the low cost of public debt and third, sustained growth in the medium-to-long term that will be able to support the economy when the ECB and other EU governments lift the current stimuli. If Italy is successful in reforming its economy, public debt will start falling and it will then not constitute a problem for the rest of Europe. Currently, however, the stability of the Italian economy – and the sustainability of its debt – still poses a serious threat to EU and Eurozone stability. This is because it relies on two things: the international credibility of Prime Minister, Mario Draghi – “mister whatever it takes,” who saved the euro - and on the purchasing programmes of the ECB - the QE–programmes (Quantitative Easing) that Draghi helped launch. However, neither of these will last forever. A “Greek scenario” is therefore still possible for Italy. Or even worse: a complete default. What would happen if a large country like Italy defaulted? An Italian default could be transmitted to the European - and global - economy through three channels: trade, the financial market, and the Eurosystem. ∗Svend E. Hougaard Jensen, PhD, is Professor of Economics at CBS, Director of the Pension Research Centre (PeRCent) at CBS, Member of the Systemic Risk Council and Non-Resident Fellow at Bruegel, Brussels. Andrea Tafuro, PhD, is postdoc in the Department of Economics at CBS. 1
The first is related to the depressive effects of a default that would reduce Italian demand for goods and services from abroad, with possible global repercussions. The second relates to the impact of an Italian default on the assets of financial institutions: banks and other financial institutions hold sovereign bonds as assets, because they are considered a safe investment and can be used as collateral for operations on the market or with the central bank. If a European country, like Italy, defaults, a share of these assets will suddenly have a value close to zero and this would impair the solvency of many financial institutions. Even financial institutions that do not hold Italian bonds could feel an impact because they might hold debt or equity of banks that became insolvent. This might lead to a generalised credit crunch, similar to the one observed in 2008, with devastating effects. For a sense of scale, consider the collapse of Lehman Brothers, which involved assets of just $600 billion. An Italian default would involve assets of app. €2,500 billion. Thanks to the QE and the overall reforms introduced by the EU after the Greek crisis, the possibility of transmission through the banking system and the financial markets has decreased. In the case of Italy, the share of sovereign debt held by non-residents declined from 50% before the Great Financial Crisis (GFC) to 35% in 2019. However, this reduces only the direct effect that an Italian default will exert on European financial institutions: the second-wave effect – the one due to the interconnectedness of financial institutions – will still be present and can become harmful if there is financial turmoil. In fact, a large share of the Italian debt now appears on the ECB balance sheet, as ECB assets, because of QE. Already before the pandemic, the Eurosystem owned about 16.5% of the total government debt of the Euro Area, with mild fluctuations across countries, except for Greece. This implies that at the end of 2019, the Eurosystem held about 20% of Italian debt – something like €400 billion. According to the Bank of Italy, this amount increased in 2020 by about €150 billion, almost covering in full the extra- deficit determined by the pandemic (about €160 billion). The Eurosystem is therefore set to hold about 25% of Italian public debt. 2
As a consequence, an Italian default would cause a large loss in the ECB balance sheets. The possible consequences of this are controversial. Well, a central bank does not aim at producing profits, and it can always print money “to pay its bills”. The profits from future seigniorage may be so high that central banks are allowed to pursue their goals even with negative capital (as has been the case with Chile and the Czech Republic in the past). Therefore, the only effect an Italian default would have is that Member States will receive lower dividends from the Central Banks. However, the capital loss generated by Italy’s default might also raise concerns about its ability to function effectively, and about its independence. This is particularly the case if there are reasons to believe that loss will lead to present or future money injection. Moreover, this would happen at a moment of high tension in the financial markets and high cost of debt: we would observe something unprecedented happening in unexplored territory. What would happen if markets convinced themselves that the ECB cannot pursue its mandate appropriately anymore? The consequences of such a situation can be potentially devastating. Despite this possibility, this scenario is still unlikely. In his efforts to steer Italy into calmer waters, Draghi is supported not only by a large parliamentary majority but by the EU Commission, thanks to the NextGenerationEU (NGEU). This is a large package – about €750 billion – approved by EU countries to boost EU recovery and create a greener, more digital, and more inclusive economy. Member States need to present a Recovery Plan to get access to these funds, in which they must specify the investments they want to pursue and the accompanying reforms necessary to guarantee long-term economic growth. Italy will receive the largest share of the European funds, about €205 billion in the period 2021-2026, of which €122.6 in the form of loans and €82.5 as grants. The country just presented its plan, laying out how resources will be distributed. It is an ambitious plan of reforms, with an additional fund from Italy’s own resources of about €30 billion. The plan shows three horizontal strategic priorities: Italy’s digital transition, green transition, and social inclusion. Nearly 40% of total resources are earmarked for 3
the green transition, 27% for digitalisation, and 40% for the development of the south of the country. The final plan is comprised of 6 missions and 16 components in the form of individual interventions including 48 reforms and 131 investment projects. Most of these projects are based on investments already in place or which have been already, at least partially, financed. This is because projects financed with NGEU funds need to be completed by a specific date, which rules out financing investments that are still on paper. The reforms are ambitious and concern the judicial system, public administration, legislation complexity and increased competition. The plan should guarantee a cumulated effect on GDP, over the 6 years of about 3.6%. All these reforms and investments go in the right direction, and they will free up the country’s potential. However, it is difficult to say if this will be enough to get Italy back on course. At the current stage, the plan is still a bit generic – in particular regarding how and when the reforms will be implemented. In addition, the plan does not present either a reform of taxation or reform of pension, which are crucial for a country with large tax evasion, and which spends about 17% of GDP on pensions. The feeling is that the Draghi government is well aware of the limits of its mandate. The coalition that sustains him, despite its size, is very heterogeneous: the inclusion of elements that might be perceived as divisive could diminish the support of some parties. A vast coalition was necessary though, to ensure that reforms and investments will be implemented in a country where governments do not last very long. The recovery plan has a long phase-in of almost 6 years, and Draghi’s government will probably not be at the helm for the entire period. It is therefore necessary that all the major elements across the political spectrum are involved, so that they will not backpedal on the reforms that they contributed to approving. However, this is also Draghi’s government’s main weakness: The need to retain their broad consensus makes it difficult to implement high impact reforms – which are generally politically costly in the short-term. If this turns out to be the case, the NGEU will become another lost opportunity for the Italian economy, and the probability of a “Greek scenario” will increase. 4
Table 1. Forecast on Italy, 2020-2022 2020 2021 2022 Government balance -9.5% -11.7% -5.8% Government debt 155.8% 159.8% 156.6% Economic growth -8.9% 4.2% 4.4% Note: The table presents the Spring Forecast for the Italian economy made by the EU commission. Source: European Commission, April 2021 References Archer, D. and Moser-Boehm, P., 2013. “Central bank finances”, BIS Working Paper No 71 Bruegel, 2021, “Bruegel database of sovereign bond holdings developed in Merler and Pisani- Ferry (2012)”, Database extracted on May 2021 Buiter, W., 2008, “Can central banks go broke?”, No 6827, CEPR Discussion Papers, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers Cohen-Setton, J., 2015, “Blogs review: QE and central bank solvency”, Bruegel De Grauwe, P., and Ji Y., 2015, “Quantitative easing in the Eurozone: It's possible without fiscal transfers”, VoxEU.org, 15 January. European Commission, 2021, “European Economic Forecast – Spring 2021”, April Government of Italy, 2021, “National Recovery and Resilience Plan (Piano nazionale di Ripresa e Resilienza)”, Governo Italiano Aprile 2021 Stella, P., 1997, “Do central banks need capital?” International Monetary Fund Working Paper No. 83, pp. 1-39. Winkler, A., 2014, “The ECB as lender of last resort. Banks versus governments”, LSE Financial Markets Group, Special Paper Series, February. 5
You can also read