Giving an Inch and Keeping a Mile: Why the Corn Lobby Let the Ethanol Tax Credit Expire
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
V. 15 no. 5 • May/Jun 2012 Giving an Inch and Keeping a Mile: Why the Corn Lobby Let the Ethanol Tax Credit Expire Aaron Smith With growing concerns about gridlock The RFS mandates that a minimum in Washington and greed on Wall quantity of ethanol be blended into Ten percent of motor gasoline in the Street, Americans are wondering gasoline each year. It was first intro United States is comprised of ethanol whether anyone with a stake in public duced in the U.S. Energy Policy Act of produced from corn. This production policies is willing to sacrifice their short-term advantage for a greater 2005, and then expanded in the U.S. level is required by law, a requirement that confers large benefits on corn good. Well, someone just did. Without Energy Independence and Security Act producers by keeping corn demand any opposition from the biofuels sector, of 2007. Under the expanded RFS, corn and prices high. In comparison, the the tax credit for ethanol blenders (the ethanol now comprises 10% of finished Volumetric Ethanol Excise Tax Credit motor gasoline in the United States, recently expired ethanol tax credit was –VEETC) expired on January 1. a small perk. up from 3% in 2005. In a recent paper, Bob Dinneen, President and CEO, Colin Carter, Gordon Rausser, and I Renewable Fuels Association, estimate that the 2007 expansion in the 1/5/12. RFA press release. RFS caused a persistent 30% increase O n January 1 of this year, defi in the price of corn. Moreover, the RFS Also in this issue cit hawks, environmentalists, has created a vulnerable corn market livestock producers, and food in which even the slightest production The Logic and Consequences of processors celebrated the expiration of disturbance in 2012 will have devastat Labeling GMOs the Volumetric Ethanol Excise Tax credit ing consequences for the world’s poor. (VEETC). This federal program, which In 2011, about 15% of global corn David Zilberman..............................5 had existed in various forms since 1978, production, or about 5% of global grain The Alpaca Bubble Revisited gave $0.45 to ethanol producers for every production, was used in U.S. corn- gallon they produced and cost taxpay ethanol production. One-third of this Tina L. Saitone and ers $6 billion in 2011. So why did the quantity returns to the food system in Richard J. Sexton.............................9 corn-ethanol lobby let it expire without the form of ethanol by-products that an apparent fight? Did they really “sac can be used as animal feed, so the net rifice their short-term advantage for the loss to the food system is 3.3% of global public good” as suggested by the above grain production. Figure 1 shows that quote from the CEO of the national trade this volume of grain is substantial: it association for the U.S. ethanol industry? exceeds total corn consumption on In this article, I argue that the the African continent. It also exceeds VEETC generated small benefits relative total rice consumption in all coun to the benefits the ethanol industry tries other than China and India. reaps from legislation known as the Re The price effects from turning food newable Fuel Standard (RFS). As such, into fuel have particularly devastating the industry was willing to let the consequences for consumers in less- VEETC expire so as to earn political developed countries, where a relatively points in its fight to preserve the RFS. large percentage of income is spent on
to look to ethanol as an alternative Figure 1. Grain Consumption in 2011/2012 market for their crops. However, the 500 attempt to make ethanol profitable failed 450 Rice because newly discovered oil reserves Wheat 400 in the U.S. Southwest kept petroleum Corn for Animal Feed 350 production high and prices low. Corn for Food 300 After 50 years of low oil prices, the Ethanol by-products 250 Arab oil embargo and the associated Ethanol (net) oil price spikes in the 1970s gave new 200 hope to ethanol advocates. However, 150 ethanol production remained far from 100 cost effective; even when oil prices 50 peaked in 1980, the cost of producing 0 ethanol was double that of gasoline. U.S. Africa EU China India Data Source: USDA FAS, PS&D Database. Outside the U.S., the corn-for-food category includes The 1978 Energy Tax Act marked industrial use. the beginning of the current wave of food, and where grains, rather than combustion engine and the automobile. federal programs to support ethanol processed foods, constitute the major In the mid-1800s, some early internal production; it included a subsidy that portion of the diet. According to the combustion engines were fueled by etha exempted ethanol/gasoline blends from Food and Agriculture Organization nol, and ethanol was used extensively the gasoline excise tax. This subsidy (FAO) of the United Nations, grains for lighting. One may wonder whether existed until the end of 2011, although comprised 57% of calories consumed ethanol could have established itself as a its magnitude and form changed in least-developed countries in 2007 viable motor fuel if it had not been sub somewhat. In its last four years, the but only 22% in the U.S. and 27% ject to the alcohol excise tax. However, subsidy took the form of a 45 cent per in the European Union. World Bank after industrial alcohol was made exempt gallon tax credit to firms that blend economists Maros Ivanic and Will from the excise tax and the price of etha ethanol with gasoline (the VEETC). Martin estimate that when the World nol consequently dropped by at least This program cost taxpayers about Bank’s food-price index jumped by 75%, it still remained double the price of $30 billion between 2005 and 2011. approximately 30% in 2010, 44 million gasoline. Abundant petroleum supplies, Although the RFS was not enacted people were forced below the extreme especially in Pennsylvania, made gaso until 2005, bills containing variants poverty line of $US 1.25 per day. line inexpensive and it seems unlikely of the RFS entered the U.S. Congress that ethanol could have established regularly between 1978 and 2004. In History itself as a motor fuel even if it had not chronological order, these bills were Ethanol, also known as ethyl alco been subject to the alcohol excise tax. the Gasohol Motor Fuel Act of 1978 hol, is the type of alcohol in alcoholic By 1920, the picture looked differ (S.2533), the Ethanol Motor Fuel Act beverages. It became a significant ent. The Pennsylvania oilfields were of 1987 (H.R.2052, S.1304), Amend motor-fuel ingredient in the United in decline and the U.S. Geological ment to the Energy Policy Act of 1992 States only recently, but it has a long Survey estimated that peak petroleum (H.AMDT.554), Renewable Fuels Acts history as a prospective motor fuel. production would be reached within of 2000 and 2001 (S.2503 and S.670. This history has been punctuated by a few years. This assessment raised IS), and the Energy Policy Acts of government action. The first such expectations that ethanol distilled from 2003 and 2004 (H.R.4503, S.2095). action came in 1862, when the Lincoln grains and potatoes would become the However, declining oil prices through administration imposed a large excise dominant motor fuel. Articles express out the 1980s meant that large-scale tax on alcohol to help fund the Civil ing this expectation appeared regularly ethanol production remained unprofit War. This tax quadrupled the price of in major newspapers such as the Los able. Ethanol comprised less than 1% both drinkable and fuel alcohol and Angeles Times and the New York Times. of finished motor gasoline in 1990. persisted until 1906, when the Free At about this same time, European The 1990 amendments to the Clean Alcohol Act made industrial alcohol agricultural production recovered from Air Act provided the next opportunity exempt from the alcohol excise tax. World War I, which led U.S. agricul for the corn ethanol industry to lobby The 1862–1906 period coincided tural prices to drop. These lower prices for favorable legislation. The amend with the development of the internal motivated U.S. agricultural producers ments required that, in regions prone 2 Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics • University of California
to poor air quality, oxygenate additives Figure 2. Actual and Predicted Corn Price be blended into gasoline to make it 7 burn more cleanly. When the amend Actual Price 6 ments were first introduced to Congress Ethanol Frozen at 2005 Level 5 in 1987, ethanol and methyl tertiary Price $/bu 4 butyl ether (MTBE), a natural-gas 3 derivative, were the main contenders 2 to fulfill the oxygenate requirement. 1 Johnson and Libecap documented 0 the lobbying battle between advocates 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 for ethanol and those for MTBE. MTBE Note: The price is the average daily cash bid in Central Illinois during March of each year. Counterfactual prediction taken from Carter, Rausser, and Smith (2012). became the dominant additive because it was less expensive, but subsequent capacity existed and 1.8 billion gallons implies a loss of 2.3 billion bushels to leaks in underground storage tanks of capacity was under construction. the food system, equivalent to about caused MTBE to contaminate drink One year later capacity under construc 16% of the total U.S. supply of corn. ing water supplies and it was conse tion had tripled and represented more If these 2.3 billion bushels were quently banned in at least 25 states. production than existed at the time. returned to the food system, users The demise of MTBE allowed etha The ethanol construction boom would increase consumption and farm nol to establish itself as a fuel additive gave the corn market fair warning of ers would reduce production until in the 2005 Energy Policy Act, which an impending increase in demand and prices had declined enough to absorb essentially replaced the oxygenate enabled it to absorb the initial onslaught. the excess supply. A simple calcula requirement with the Renewable Fuel Inventories accumulated and a record tion can give a ballpark estimate of how Standard. Legislation to increase the number of corn acres were planted in much prices would decline. In recent RFS entered Congress even before the 2007. However, production has not kept research, Michael Adjemian and I esti 2005 Energy Policy Act had passed, up with demand. According to the most mate that in recent years corn users and more bills followed in 2006 recent USDA estimates, carryover stocks would be willing to consume 2% more (the 20/20 Biofuels Challenge Act of into the 2012 crop year will be only corn for every 10% reduction in price. 2005 (S.1609), BOLD Energy Act of 6.7% of annual use. Carryover stocks Nathan Hendricks, a 2011 UC 2006 (S.2571.IS, H.R.5331.IH)). have only been this low once since Davis graduate, estimated in his PhD These proposals led to the 2007 1950. In 1995 poor weather caused low dissertation that U.S. farmers would expansion of the RFS, which specified crop yield and low inventory, but the plant 3% fewer acres to corn for every minimum renewable-fuel production effect was temporary because inventory 10% reduction in price. Summing these each calendar year from 2007 through was replenished by the next harvest. In effects implies that the market could 2022. It required 9 billion gallons in contrast, the market shock that caused absorb 5% more corn for every 10% 2008, with annual increases to 15.2 bil low inventory this year is a legislated price reduction. Thus, returning 16% lion gallons in 2012 and 36 billion gal permanent increase in demand. of supply to the food system would lons in 2022. However, no more than The current price of corn on the reduce corn prices by about 32% 13.2 billion gallons of corn ethanol Chicago Mercantile Exchange is about This simple calculation is consistent may be used to satisfy the RFS in 2012, $6.00 per bushel—almost triple the with the dynamic analysis in my recent and no more than 15 billion gallons pre-mandate levels. What would the work with Colin Carter and Gordon of ethanol may be used after 2015. price be if ethanol production had been Rausser. In that paper, we isolate three frozen at 2005 levels? In the 2005–06 main effects of the 2007 RFS expansion, Effect of the RFS on Corn Prices crop year, 1.6 billion bushels of corn each of which are apparent in Figure The 2007 RFS expansion caused etha were used to produce ethanol; in the 2. First, the corn market anticipated nol plants to sprout across the coun 2011–12 crop year, 5.0 billion bushels. the forthcoming ethanol boom and try and especially in the Midwest. When corn is processed into ethanol, increased inventory demand accordingly. Firms could enter the ethanol industry approximately one third of its caloric As a result, prices increased in 2006 in secure in the knowledge that the gov value is retained in a by-product known advance of the ethanol-production jump ernment had guaranteed demand for as distiller’s grains that is fed to animals. in 2007 and 2008. Second, we estimate their product. At the end of 2005, 4.3 Thus, an increase of 3.4 billion bushels that corn prices would have been, on billion gallons of ethanol-producing of corn used for ethanol production average, 30% lower from 2006 through Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics • University of California 3
rise even further and plunge millions Figure 3. Ethanol Operating Margin more people into extreme poverty. If 1.00 they weren’t constrained by mandates, 0.75 then ethanol producers would respond to high prices by reducing their use of $/gal 0.5 corn. Jim Costa (D-Fresno) and Bob Goodlatte (R-Va.) recently introduced 0.25 legislation that would allow such a 0.00 response; under their proposal the 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 mandate would be reduced when corn Note: Data from the Center for Agricultural and Rural Development, Iowa State University, stockpiles are low. This proposal is a www.card.iastate.edu/research/bio/tools/hist_eth_gm.aspx. small step in the right direction, but any 2010 had no increase in the demand for ethanol producers over operating costs proposed weakening of the RFS will be corn from ethanol producers occurred. declined by the amount of the tax credit met by strong opposition from lobbying Our third finding is that a below-average at the end of 2011. This drop erased organizations such as Renewable Fuels harvest in 2010 caused inventory to be the large operating margins that etha Association, the National Corn Grow run down and prices to be about 50% nol refiners had enjoyed in the last half ers Association, and Growth Energy. above where they would have been if of 2011 when strong export demand An abbreviated version of this article ap ethanol production had been frozen at kept ethanol prices high. Moreover, peared in American.com magazine on 2005 levels. These results show that it explains why ethanol production January 4, 2012. See www.american.com/ archive/2012/january/children-of-the the effect of ethanol on corn prices gets has not declined in 2012: after remov corn-the-renewable-fuels-disaster. magnified when inventory is low. ing the tax credit, ethanol production at 2011 levels remains profitable. Suggested Citation: Effect of Removing the Tax Credit Smith, A. 2012. "Giving an Inch and At most, removing the VEETC could Outlook for the Future Keeping a Mile: Why the Corn Lobby Let the Ethanol Tax Credit Expire.” ARE have caused ethanol production to drop Removal of the ethanol tax credit has Update 15(5):1-4. University of California to mandated levels. In 2011, ethanol had a negligible effect on corn prices Giannini Foundation of Agricultural production exceeded the mandate by 1.3 because high export demand is hold Economics. billion gallons. Most of this excess was ing up ethanol prices, which makes exported to Brazil, Canada, the United above-mandate ethanol production Aaron Smith is an associate professor in the Kingdom, and the Netherlands to meet profitable. Even if export demand Department of Agricultural and Resource biofuel mandates in those countries. declines, the RFS guarantees that etha Economics at UC Davis. He can be reached by A bushel of corn produces about 2.7 nol production could only drop by a e-mail at adsmith@ucdavis.edu. gallons of ethanol, so above-mandate small amount this year and would have For further information, the ethanol production used 0.48 billion to increase in the next few years as the author recommends: bushels of corn and, after accounting for RFS increases to its long-term level of Adjemian, M.K. and A. Smith. “Using distiller’s grains, it removed 0.32 billion 15 billion gallons per year. By keeping USDA Forecasts to Estimate the bushels from the food system or 2.2% of ethanol production high, the RFS places Price Flexibility of Demand for total U.S. supply. Thus, if all above-man a high floor under the corn price; corn Agricultural Commodities.” Ameri date ethanol production became unprof prices will remain high as long as the can Journal of Agricultural Eco itable upon removal of the tax credit, RFS is in place. It is for this reason that nomics 94(4)(2012): 978-995. the calculations above imply that corn Jon Doggett, vice president of public Carter, C.A., G.C. Rausser, and A. prices would have dropped by only 4.4% policy for the National Corn Grow Smith. “The Effect of the U.S. However, ethanol production has ers Association, commented recently Ethanol Mandate on Corn Prices.” 2012. Working paper, available declined little, if at all, since the removal that his members “view the RFS as from http://asmith.ucdavis.edu. of the tax credit. In the first quarter of more important than the farm bill.” Johnson, R.N. and G.D Libecap. 2012, the United States exported about The RFS has caused carryover “Information Distortion and a quarter of a billion gallons of ethanol, stocks to be run down and has placed Competitive Remedies in Gov and so it is on pace to produce about the corn market in a perilous posi ernment Transfer Programs: The the same amount of ethanol as last tion. If the 2012 crop is even slightly Case of Ethanol.” Economics of year. Figure 3 shows that the return to smaller than expected, then prices will Governance 2(2001): 101–34. 4 Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics • University of California
The Logic and Consequences of Labeling Genetically Modified Organisms David Zilberman informational needs of people who want radiation or other chemicals. The to avoid GMOs. Anyone who is strongly discovery of DNA and advances The choice facing California is not opposed to buying GM products is free in modern molecular biology have whether consumers should have to do so, as USDA “certified organic” allowed the development of more information regarding consuming GMOs because non-GM food can be products do not contain GMOs. refined and precise crop breeding labeled as such, but what will be the The real issue of the proposition is techniques where varieties are slightly benchmark for labeling requirements. the benchmark required for mandatory modified by adding specific traits. Scientific research findings have not labeling. Right now, the benchmark is Obviously, GMO technologies are found GM food to be riskier to health proven toxicity or meaningful health still in their infancy, but the cost of ob or the environment than other foods. effects; thus, the government has rightly taining genomic knowledge is declining Furthermore, there is evidence that required the labeling of cigarettes and exponentially and new techniques for GM food improves both human and caloric contents. GM products are not taking advantage of this knowledge are environmental health, increases yield required to be labeled because regula improving. Researchers have already and significantly reduces food prices. tory research has found them to be discovered a wide array of genetic ma as safe as conventional foods. People nipulations that can improve pest who have additional requirements control, enhance nutritional quality, ex about food intake rely on voluntary tend shelf life, and advance other labels such as “kosher” and “halal.” aspects of crop quality and productivity. But society does not use ‘kosher’ as The early commercial applications G MOs (genetically modified the benchmark and require all “non of GMOs, namely traits to control organisms) in agriculture have kosher” foods to be labeled as such. pests, are the “low hanging fruits” of been a source of controversy From an economic perspective, label research efforts and, as experience with since their introduction in the mid ing GMOs makes sense if the net ben transgenic tools is accumulated, it is 1990s. On the one hand, the planting efit from having it outweighs the cost. likely that more appealing traits (i.e., of GM varieties has spread rapidly. In While some people may feel strongly drought tolerance, nitrogen fixation, the case of soybeans, more than 70% against GMOs and may vote for the etc.) will be developed. The applica of total acreage used for their cultiva proposition because their perceived tion of genetic engineering techniques tion is of some type of GM variety. benefits from labeling are very high, in agriculture has been advancing more However, GM varieties have not been I suspect that there are many others slowly relative to that of medicine, but adopted in major crops like wheat, rice, who are indifferent or only slightly as we will show, even the existing traits and potatoes, and are banned in the EU concerned about GM varieties, yet have made an immense difference. and most African countries. There has may be unaware of the environmental been continuous debate over the regu and social benefits of GMOs and the How Have GMOs Made lation of GM varieties, and California potential negative consequences of a Difference? voters now face a proposition that will labeling. The purpose of this article is A large body of literature has been accu require the labeling of food that con to provide research results on the ben mulated to assess the impact of GMOs tains genetically modified ingredients. efits of GM products and some of the on agricultural productivity and food On the surface, the main argument implications of constraining the growth prices. The major applications thus far behind the proposition is the right of and development of this technology. (Bt varieties or Round-up Ready variet individuals to know the true makeup ies) reduce insect and weed damage. of the food they eat. I agree with this On GMOs and Crop Breeding The impact on yield depends on in principle, but in the case of this Most of the food we eat today has whether the specific pest damage was particular proposition, the crux of been bred for humans and modified controlled by an alternative method. this issue has little to do with freedom through a variety of techniques. They In many cases, Bt varieties are replac of choice. In fact, voluntary labeling include traditional selective breeding, ing toxic pesticides, and the main gain of GMO-free products can meet the as well as induced mutations through is not in yield, but in improved health Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics • University of California 5
among farmers, consumers, and the Table 1. Yield, Costs, and Profitability Effects of Adopting Bt Cotton and Maize technology provider. Studies in other Insecticide Increase in Increase countries also confirm these results. Reduction Effective in Gross Country (%) Yield (%) Margin (%) References Studies that investigated the benefits Bt Cotton of adoption of GMOs around the world Argentina 47 33 23 Qaim & de Janvry 2003, 2005 have identified a wide variety of ben efits, from increased yield and reduced Australia 48 0 66 Fitt,2003 cost as mentioned above, reduced finan China 65 24 470 Pray et al. 2002 cial risk associated with farming, as well Qaim et al. 2006, India 41 37 135 as non-monetary benefits like reduced Sadashivappa & Qaim2009 pesticide exposure for farm workers and Mexico 77 9 295 Traxler et al. 2003 reduced effort associated with monitor Thurtle et al. 2003, South Africa 33 22 91 ing pests and application of pesticides. Gouse et al. 2006 United Falck-Zepeda et al. 2006, GM varieties also have significant 36 10 58 environmental and health impacts, and States Carpenter et al. 2002 Bt Maize a recent National Research Council Argentina 0 9 20 Brookes & Barfoot 2005 (NRC) report found them to be at least Brookes & Barfoot 2005, as safe as conventional food. Studies Philippines 5 34 53 from India and China suggest that adop Yorobe & Quicoy 2006 Brookes & Barfoot 2005, tion of Bt cotton led to a reduction in South Africa 10 11 42 Gouse et al. 2006 the application of pesticides and actually Spain 63 6 70 Gomez-Barbero et al.2008 saved a significant number of lives of United Naseem & Pray 2004, individuals who otherwise would have 8 5 12 States Fernandez-Cornejo & Li 2005 been exposed to toxic chemicals. Stud Source: Qaim 2009. ies suggest that Bt traits in cotton reduce and environmental sustainability. On and, as a result, prices tend to decline vulnerability to toxins that emerge in the other hand, in cases where trans which makes consumers better off. storage, and thus improve food safety. genic varieties address pest problems While farmers may have received lower The use of herbicide tolerant variet that haven’t been treated before, yield prices, they also experience lower costs ies led to increased use of Round-up, tends to increase. As a rule, adoption and higher yields. Thus, seed compa which the EPA considers to be low of Bt varieties tends to have a higher nies, farmers, and consumers may all in toxicity. But at the same time, it yield effect in developing countries share the economic benefit resulting enabled reduced tillage practices that that face severe pest problems and have from the adoption of GM varieties. in turn led to reductions in soil ero relatively limited access to technolo Several studies address the distri sion, as well as runoff of water and gies than in developed countries. bution of benefits from GM varieties chemicals. These GM varieties also Table 1 represents outcomes of during the early stages of the adoption contribute to soil carbon sequestration. multiple studies that demonstrate this of different traits in various crops from point for Bt cotton and Bt maize. The 1999 to 2005 in the United States, and Aggregate Impacts results suggest that yields may grow the results are presented in table 2. Most of the existing literature on by more than 30% in developing coun These findings suggest that the overall the impacts of GMOs considers spe tries such as India and the Philippines, gains from these early stages was very cific case studies and documents while pesticide use may decrease up high. For example, the annual gain increasing yields, reduction in costs, to 70%. Furthermore, the studies also from adoption of herbicide tolerant and some environmental benefits. compute that under plausible price soybean varieties in 1999 was between Recently, there have been attempts ranges, farmer profitability per hect $500 million and $1.1 billion and to assess the aggregate effects of are is increasing and the range of gain the gain in 2001 was $1.25 billion. GMOs on agricultural supplies and varies across countries and crops. In some cases, the consumer share agricultural commodity prices. One of the main concerns about GM was found to be greater than 50%, while Estimates based on aggregate data varieties was that they mostly benefited in others, the innovator or the farmer (annual national output of corn, cotton, technology providers, like Monsanto. share was very high. Altogether, the soybeans and rapeseed, as well as acre However, GM varieties increase supply table shows that the benefits are shared age of GM and non-GM varieties for 6 Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics • University of California
Table 2. Benefits of the Adoption of Genetically Engineered Crops and Their Distribution Total Benefits Share of Total Benefits (%) Study Year ($ Million) U.S. Farmers Innovators U.S. Consumers Net ROW Bt Cotton Falck-Zepeda et al. 1999 1996 134 43 47 6 Falck-Zepeda et al. 2000a 1996 240 59 26 9 6 Falck-Zepeda et al. 2000b 1997 190 43 44 7 6 Falck-Zepeda et al. 1999 1998 213 46 43 7 4 Frisvold et al. 2000 1996-98 131-164 5-6 46 33 18 a U.S.-EPA 2001 1996-99 16-46 NA NA NA NA Price et al. 2003 1997 210 29 35 14 22 Herbicide-Resistant Cotton Price et al. 2003 1997 232 4 6 57 33 Herbicide-Resistant Soybeans Falck-Zepeda et al. 2000b 1997-LEb 1,100 77 10 4 9 c 1997-HE 437 29 18 17 28 Moschini et al. 2000 1999 804 20 45 10 26 Price et al. 2003 1997 310 20 68 5 6 d Qaim & Traxler 2005 1997 206 16 49 35 NAe Qaim & Traxler 2005 2001 1230 13d 34 53 NAe c NA= Not applicable HE= High elasticity; assumes a U.S. soybean supply elasticity of 0.92 d ROW= Rest of the world (includes consumers and producers Includes all soybean producers a e Limited to U.S. farmers Included in consumers and producers b LE= Low elasticity; assumes a U.S. soybean supply elasticity of 0.22 Source: NRC 2010. different countries over time) confirmed led to increases in the demand for meats suggest that if the European nations that GM varieties tend to have higher and, as a result, increased demand for (and the African countries influenced yield increases in developing rather feed grains. This, combined with the by them) had adopted GMOs in their than developed countries. The average introduction of biofuel, led to significant production of corn, soybeans and other per acre yield increase associated with pressure on food prices and the rising crops, the prices of these commodities GM cotton in developing countries is prices of food after 2006 had adversely would have been substantially lower. above 50%, and it is above 35% for GM affected the well-being of the poor. The Moreover, existing regulations corn varieties. Conversely, the impacts food price inflation would have been have prevented the introduction of of GM varieties on cotton and corn in even more severe without GMOs. GM varieties in the production of rice developed countries are around 15%. Biotechnology has been one of the and wheat. Field studies suggest that The impacts of GMOs on soybean most dominant sources of the increase their impact, especially in rice, can be yields are smaller; however, the avail in supply of agricultural commodities as impressive as in corn—increasing ability of herbicide tolerant soybean and thus has contributed to a reduc yield and saving lives. Thus, the intro varieties has contributed to a near dou tion in agricultural commodity prices. duction of GM varieties to these crops bling of the total acreage of soybeans The increase in supply of soybeans in would further reduce the pressure on globally in the last twenty years. Much Argentina was of the same order of mag agricultural commodity prices and of this increase can be attributed to nitude as the increased consumption of improve economic well-being globally. double-cropping of soybeans with corn soybeans in China after 2004, thereby and wheat, so the increase in the agri neutralizing potential price hikes. GMOs and the Environment cultural footprint was much smaller. Using the same methodologies that The increase in agricultural produc The increase in agricultural produc assessed the impact of biofuel on food tivity and reduction in toxic pesticide tion due to the introduction of GMOs prices, it was found that GMOs have use associated with GM varieties can has significantly affected food prices. reduced food prices by the same order make a difference in addressing the The growing population and growing of magnitude (25% or more for corn challenges of climate change. Higher incomes in the developing world has and soybeans). Furthermore, studies yields mean that less land is required Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics • University of California 7
than other foods. Furthermore, there is Figure 1. Contractions in Agricultural Biotechnology R&D Associated with European GMO Restrictions of 1999 evidence that GM food improves both human and environmental well-being. 350 Labeling of GMOs will make GM Publications Regulatory Filings food less attractive to some consumers, 300 Field Trials Innovations in R&D reduce demand, and make investment in Projections 2003-04 250 this technology less appealing. We have the experience of the European ban of 200 GM varieties in 1999, which was asso Annual Count ciated with significant contraction in 150 investment and patenting of GM traits. As Figure 1 shows, publica 100 tions, innovations, and investment 50 in GMOs were growing throughout the 1990s but peaked just before 0 the ban was implemented. This has 9 7 1 3 7 1 3 5 9 0 8 2 4 8 2 4 6 0 slowed advancement of the technol 200 199 198 199 199 199 200 199 199 198 199 199 200 200 198 199 200 199 Source: Graff, G. et al. 2009 “The Contraction of Agbiotech Product Quality Innovation.” ogy in an era when we need it most. Nature Biotechnology 27(8). Introduction of policies that require for agricultural production; thus, the technology is the key to keeping up labeling and add any other obstacles increase in output due to GMOs has and improving welfare. Of course, bio to the evolution of GMOs may have already contributed to reduced con technology is one of many agricultural a similar effect. Voters will have to version of non-agricultural land for technologies that can play a pivotal role ask whether the potential gain associ agricultural use, e.g., deforestation. in our future. Integrating agricultural ated with labeling is worth the cost Furthermore, through soil carbon biotechnology with ecological farming associated with technological stagna sequestration and the reduction in use as well as precision agriculture can lead tion and the resulting losses in eco of inputs, production with GMOs has to a much stronger and more stable nomic and environmental welfare. contributed to significant decreases system that will allow more sound Suggested Citation: in greenhouse gas emissions. utilization of agricultural resources Zilberman, D. 2012. "The Logic and The ability of transgenic technolo with less environmental damages. Consequences of Labeling GMOs.” ARE gies to identify traits that can address Many may be concerned that tech Update 15(5):5-8. University of California disease and other issues suggests that nological developments are frequently Giannini Foundation of Agricultural these technologies can play a major subject to human error, and thus reas Economics. role in adaptation to climate change sessment and improvement of these and development of crop systems that technologies are essential. Yet, stud David Zilberman is a professor in the Department respond to changes in weather condi ies suggest that while there are cases of Agricultural and Resource Economics, at the tions. Thus, transgenic technologies of under-regulation, there are also University of California, Berkeley. He can be have contributed and can contribute frequent cases of over-regulation that contacted by e-mail at zilber11@berkeley.edu. even further to improved economic may hamper technological change and and environmental well being. innovation. Thus, design of efficient For further information, GMOs are a new technology and regimes for biotechnology is a challenge. the author recommends: they have their own limitations. Obvi ously, pest resistance has and will Conclusion “Impact of Genetically Engineered Crops on Farm Sustainability in the continue to emerge with the use of The main question is not whether con United States.” National Research GM varieties. The only way to sustain sumers should have a choice regarding Council Report 1 (2010): 270. and improve agricultural productivity their own consumption of GMOs, but is to continue to conduct research and rather whether GM foods will be the Qaim, M. “The Economics of Geneti cally Modified Crops.” Annual Review stay ahead of emerging challenges. norm and non-GM food labeled, or vice of Resource Economics 1(2009): 665 Sustainability is not a state of nir versa. Mainstream scientific research 694. vana; rather, evolution occurs and findings have not found GM food to be advanced scientific knowledge and riskier to health or the environment 8 Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics • University of California
The Alpaca Bubble Revisited Tina L. Saitone and Richard J. Sexton I n the January/February 2006 issue “factor price equalization theorem” of ARE Update, we published an indicated that, in equilibrium, prices We revisit the U.S. alpaca industry six article on the burgeoning U.S. alpaca for live alpacas in the United States years after having conducted a study industry entitled “Do Alpacas Rep and Peru should equalize apart from suggesting the industry was in the some minor differences due to fiber resent the Latest Speculative Bubble midst of an unsustainable speculative in Agriculture?” The research was quality and fiber shipping costs. bubble. We show that in the aftermath motivated by the dramatic growth of That point was important to our the bubble has largely burst. We also offer some lessons intended to prevent the industry in the United States, the argument because industry proponents the recurrence of such bubbles in curious marketing practices (such claimed that the market for alpaca agriculture. as advertising the benefits of rais fiber was poised to grow rapidly. Thus, ing alpacas on cable television), and the case could be made that the high the remarkable prices paid for alpaca alpaca prices observed at the time of stock. We reported rapidly escalat our study were the product of rational ing prices at several alpaca auctions, investments in a high-growth industry. with mean auction prices in 2004 of Our analysis showed that an annual $26,000 and $31,000 for the two major sustained growth rate in fiber prices breeds, Huacaya and Suri, respectively. of at least 20% was needed to justify Our analysis strongly suggested the live-animal prices observed at the that these prices were unsustainable time. The demand growth needed to and that alpacas represented the latest sustain such a rate of price increase example of a speculative bubble in would be almost unprecedented for agriculture. The economic basis for an agricultural product. Moreover, our conclusion was rather straightfor the potential for fiber exports from ward. First, fiber, the single marketable the dominant Peruvian herd and pro product produced by an alpaca, was in duction from a rapidly growing U.S. most cases valued at less than the vari herd meant that supply could respond able costs of maintaining an alpaca. to rising prices to preclude dramatic Second, alpacas are native to Peru, and sustained price increases. which is home to the world’s larg est alpaca herd of roughly 3.5 million The Story Six Years Later animals. In contrast, by 2009 there Our purpose in this paper is to exam were about 150,000 registered alpacas ine what has happened in the inter in the United States. Although pre vening years since this study was Prices for alpacas sold at auction between cise statistics on the value of alpacas published and to distill the lessons that 2005 through 2011 declined each year by several thousand dollars, with the largest in Peru were difficult to obtain, nev can be learned. We recently gathered annual decline of $8,000 occurring between ertheless it was abundantly clear auction price data (1,493 observations) 2007 and 2008. that Peruvian alpacas sold for, at for alpacas, similar to those analyzed most, a few hundred U.S. dollars. in the original study, for the interven Trade in live animals between the ing years since that study. The prices U.S. and Peru was prohibited because from alpaca auctions between 2005 of concerns about animal disease and 2011 are likely not representa transmission. But there were and still tive of all alpaca prices because the are no barriers to trade for alpaca sampled auctions tend to attract the fiber. Thus, a straightforward appli alpacas considered to be of the high cation of what economists call the est quality. The reported prices also Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics • University of California 9
per animal in our 2006 study. Those Figure 1. Average Decline in Alpaca Price, Relative to 2005 costs are likely modestly higher today. 0 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 An informal examination of fiber sales offers on the Internet in a variety -5,000 of locations revealed a wide range of Average Auction Price Difference Relative to 2005 ($) offered sales prices, with $10–12 per -10,000 lb. roughly representing the upper end of the sales price distribution. Thus, if -15,000 the entire 6.5 lbs. of fleece yielded by a typical alpaca could be sold for this price (an unlikely proposition), its mar -20,000 ketable product would be worth at most $65–78 per year, less than half the con -25,000 servatively estimated maintenance costs. -30,000 Lessons to Be Learned History suggests that speculative -35,000 bubbles come along relatively regularly in agriculture, and they can cause overstate actual sales values because while the female price declined by a much financial hardship to those who owners can set a minimum reserve factor of 3.5—leading to a near con get caught up in them. In a longer price in the auction; if no price is vergence of male and female prices by version of our ARE Update paper (see offered above the reserve, the auction 2011. The uptick in male prices in 2007 the Further Reading box), we provide records a sale at the reserve price to is due largely to two sales recorded a brief history of such bubbles and the original owner. Nonetheless, trends in excess of $200,000 in that year. some telltale warning signs. Bubbles in prices in these auctions will reflect If indeed the 2011 figures repre are common for products that can be overall trends in the alpaca market. sent actual sales and not just pro produced on relatively small parcels. Our approach was to specify a spective sellers’ hopes in the form In addition to alpacas, ostriches, simple statistical model that expressed of reserve prices, then they indicate chinchillas, Shetland ponies, emus, an alpaca’s price as a function of its type that although most of the air has Berkshire hogs, and Merino sheep (Huacaya or Suri), gender, the specific escaped from the alpaca bubble, some are examples of livestock that have auction at which the animal was sold remains. Purchases at these prices experienced speculative bubbles. (Alpaca Owners and Breeders Asso must reflect the actions of those who The bubbles are also marked by a ciation, Breeder’s Choice, America’s hold out hope for the industry’s recov paucity of outside, objective informa Choice, and Futurity), and the year in ery and are acquiring what they con tion and a group of investors who com which the animal was sold. The primary sider to be prime breeding stock. municate primarily among themselves. focus of our interest was the effect of A poignant story can also be told For example, when we first began work the sales year on auction price. All of from perusing commercial websites on the alpaca industry, we were sur these results were statistically signifi such as Craigslist. Here, one can find prised to find no objective economic cant at the 90% level or greater and are offers to give away alpacas or to sell studies, even though the U.S. alpaca summarized in the chart in figure 1. entire herds for a tiny fraction of what herd was growing rapidly and was Figure 1 shows that prices declined a single animal would have fetched present to a degree in every state. in every year (relative to the base year several years ago. For an owner who Bubbles are also characterized by of 2005). The decline in price in each doesn’t attach an intrinsic value to the absence of what economists who year is several thousand dollars, with owning alpacas as pets or “rural lawn study the phenomena refer to as the the largest annual decline of $8,000 mowers,” the offer to give them away “smart money,” i.e., sophisticated inves occurring between 2007 and 2008. is economically rational, given that tors. In agriculture, among the “smart Figure 2 shows the mean annual male their marketable fiber is typically worth money” investors would be experi and female alpaca price in our dataset. less than their maintenance cost. For enced agriculturalists or agribusiness The figure shows the male price fell example, we reported annual mainte firms, none of whom became involved by a factor of five between 2005–2011, nance costs in the range of $169–$308 in the alpaca industry. Inability to 10 Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics • University of California
“short” an asset also makes it more Figure 2. Average Auction Prices for Male and Female Alpacas, 2005–2011 vulnerable to a speculative bubble because informed investors have no 80,000 way to arbitrage a price that is objec 70,000 Average Auction Price ($) tively too high through short sales. Females Males 60,000 Our own experience in the after math of conducting the first alpaca 50,000 study is also instructive. Not surpris 40,000 ingly, it caused a considerable stir among alpaca owners but there was 30,000 little attempt to address the economic 20,000 content of our work. Instead, various 10,000 “theories” abounded that served in the minds of many to debunk our work 0 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 and discredit us. For example, one of us was claimed to be a disgruntled themselves, and they were driven to alpaca inseminator from Florida. In find whatever devices they could to For further reading, another case we were asserted to be discredit the work in their minds and the authors recommend: UC Davis undergraduate students who restore consonance among their beliefs. Saitone, T.L. and R.J. Sexton. “Alpaca conducted the study as part of a mar Had more heeded the warnings early Lies? Speculative Bubbles in Agricul keting class. Yet another claim is that on, they could have salvaged much of ture: Why they Happen and How to our study was UC Davis’ revenge for their investments but of course, in the Recognize Them.” Review of Agricul the Alpaca Registry no longer using UC process of doing so they would have tural Economics 29(2007): 286-305. Davis to conduct alpaca DNA tests. collapsed the bubble even sooner. An alternative form of critique was Finally, as we noted, there is some to focus on a single fact or assumption evidence from the auction sales that a employed in the study, such as the price bit of air remains in the bubble. The of a bale of hay, argue that it was incor harsh reality is that, whereas some may rect, and thereby claim that the entire want to hold alpacas as pets or lawn study and its conclusions could be sum mowers, an animal should not fetch marily dismissed. Because there was more than a few hundred dollars, and considerable variability reported in pro they should not be held as investments. duction costs and fiber prices, we erred Suggested Citation: on the side of conservatism throughout the process of conducting the original Saitone, T.L. and R.J. Sexton. 2012. "The Alpaca Bubble Revisted." ARE Update study, conducting simulations for a 15(5):9-11. University of California wide range of values for fiber, alpaca Giannini Foundation of Agricultural costs of production, and discount Economics. rates. The inescapable conclusion was that no set of market conditions could sustain the alpaca prices pre Tina L. Saitone is a post-doctoral scholar in vailing at the time. Some of this inter Agricultural and Resource Economics (ARE) at change among industry participants, UC Davis. She can be reached at saitone@primal. ucdavis.edu. Richard J. Sexton is professor and now several years old, is preserved on department chair in ARE at UC Davis. He can be this website: www.alpacanation.com/ reached at rich@primal.ucdavis.edu. forum/topic.asp?TOPIC_ID=2327. Such reactions are readily predicted by the theory of cognitive dissonance from psychology. Our study’s conclu sions were dramatically at odds with beliefs alpaca owners held among Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics • University of California 11
Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics UC Davis One Shields Avenue Davis CA 95616 GPBS Agricultural and ARE Update is published six times per year by the Resource Economics Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics, University of California. UPDATE Domestic subscriptions are available free of charge to interested parties. Co-Editors To subscribe to ARE Update by mail contact: Richard Sexton Julie McNamara, Outreach Coordinator Sofia Berto Villas-Boas Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics David Zilberman Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics Managing Editor University of California and Desktop Publisher One Shields Avenue, Davis, CA 95616 E-mail: julie@primal.ucdavis.edu Julie McNamara Phone: 530-752-5346 Published by the To receive notification when new issues of the ARE Update are available Giannini Foundation of online, submit an e-mail request to join our listserv to Agricultural Economics julie@primal.ucdavis.edu. Articles published herein may be reprinted in their entirety with the author’s or editors’ permission. Please credit the Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics, University of California. http://giannini.ucop.edu ARE Update is available online at http://giannini.ucop.edu/are-update/ The University of California is an Equal Opportunity/Affirmative Action employer.
You can also read