Crude Oil Prices and the USD/EUR Exchange Rate
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Crude Oil Prices and the USD/EUR Exchange Rate Andreas This paper investigates the impact of changes in the U.S. dollar/euro exchange rate on crude Breitenfellner, oil prices. The negative correlation of these two variables is ascribed to five possible channels: Jesús Crespo on the supply side, the purchasing power of oil export revenues and on the demand side, local Cuaresma1 prices in non-U.S. dollar regions, investments in crude oil-related asset markets, the monetary policy regime in oil-exporting countries and the efficiency of the currency market. We give evidence that using information on the U.S. dollar/euro exchange rate (and its determinants) significantly improves oil price forecasts. We discuss the possible implications these results might suggest with regard to the stabilization of oil prices or the adjustment of global imbal- ances. JEL classification: C53, F31, Q43 Keywords: oil price, exchange rate, forecasting, multivariate time series models Due to the recent oil price shock, econ- variables which are captured through omists have increasingly devoted their the evolution of the exchange rate. efforts to the analysis of energy mar- Five possible channels of the nega- kets. Similarly, the continuous build-up tive relation between the U.S. dollar of global imbalances keeps raising econ- and crude oil prices can be put forward: omists’ interest in exchange rate issues. a purchasing power channel, a local Despite these co-occurring events, little price channel, an investment channel, a attention has been paid to the relation monetary policy channel and a cur- between oil prices and exchange rates. rency market channel. These five chan- Only few economists have shown an nels can be derived from the following active interest in the following ques- five hypotheses: First, oil-exporting tion: Is it just a coincidence that crude countries aim to stabilize the purchas- oil prices have been soaring while, ing power of their (U.S. dollar) export simultaneously, the U.S. dollar has revenues in terms of their (predomi- depreciated to reach a record low (and nately euro-denominated and not U.S. vice versa)? dollar-denominated) imports. Second, In this study we analyze the in- the U.S. dollar’s depreciation makes oil formation content of the USD/EUR less expensive for consumers in non- exchange rate for forecasting oil prices, U.S. dollar regions (in local currency), using monthly data from 1983 to 2006. thereby increasing their crude oil In particular, we analyze whether in- demand, which eventually causes adjust- cluding information on the exchange ments in the oil price denominated in rate and its determinants in simple time U.S. dollars. Third, a falling U.S. dollar series models of the oil price improves reduces the returns on U.S. dollar- the models’ predictive power. The denominated financial assets in foreign effects found here may also be reflect- currencies, increasing the attractive- ing indirect effects of other economic ness of oil and other commodities as a 1 andreas.breitenfellner@oenb.at; Oesterreichische Nationalbank, Foreign Research Division; jesus.crespo- cuaresma@uibk.ac.at; University of Innsbruck, Department of Economics. The authors would like to thank Monika Psenner; Doris Ritzberger-Grünwald, Martin Summer and the participants of internal research seminars Refereed by: at the Oesterreichische Nationalbank, the European Central Bank and the Banque de France as well as the Franz Wirl, participants of the “Enerday” Conference in Dresden in April 2008 for many helpful comments on earlier drafts of University of Vienna this paper, and Andreas Nader for data assistance. 102 MONETARY POLICY & THE ECONOMY Q4/08
Crude Oil Prices and the USD/EUR Exchange Rate class of alternative assets to foreign in- 2006), it is not obvious that this rec- vestors. Commodity assets also serve as ommendation will have an impact. In- a hedge against inflation, since the U.S. deed, it is usually argued that petro- dollar’s depreciation raises the risk of dollar recycling may have exacerbated inflationary pressures in the United global imbalances as it may have alle- States. Fourth, the U.S. dollar’s depre- viated the dampening effect of the ciation entails monetary easing else- current oil price shock on European where, including in oil-producing growth (European Commission, 2006). countries with currencies pegged to Furthermore, the impact of oil prices the U.S. dollar. In turn, lower interest on Europe has already been moderated rates increase liquidity, thereby stimu- by the appreciation of its currencies lating demand, including demand for – in particular of the euro – vis-à-vis oil. Fifth, foreign exchange markets are the U.S. dollar. All in all, this did not possibly more efficient than oil markets sufficiently curb European oil demand; and hence anticipate developments in oil prices continued to rise and contrib- the real economy that affect the demand uted further to unbalanced current for and supply of oil. account deficits in the U.S.A. Apart from the obvious motivation This contribution is also related to of enlarging our understanding of oil the research agenda on the connection markets and improving oil price fore- between commodity prices, currencies casts, there are also a number of perti- and their fundamentals. Chen et al. nent economic debates related to this (2008) successfully forecast commodity research path. One hotly debated issue, prices with the use of exchange rates for instance, is the contribution of oil- of important “commodity currencies,” exporting countries to persistent global i.e. of economies with floating ex- imbalances. The surge in oil prices change rates and a substantial share of since the end of the 1990s has led to commodities in their exports. The ex- rising current account surpluses of oil- planation to this nexus provided by exporting countries that outpace those Chen et al. (2008) relates to the fact of Asian emerging economies and that commodity currencies embody whose levels correspond to a large important information about future extent to U.S. current account deficits. commodity price movements, while As a consequence, the U.S. Treasury commodity markets are less forward- suggested that “oil exporters should consi- looking. In this sense our paper can be der the role that the choice of foreign seen as an extension to the approach on exchange regime can play in the adjustment non-commodity currencies adopted by process” (McCown et al., 2006). The Chen et al. (2008), while at the same IMF concludes from this debate that time presenting complementary expla- “[h]igher spending [of oil-producing coun- nations to that approach. tries] … would help … contribute to re- This paper is organized as follows. ducing global imbalances” (IMF, 2006, Section 1 shows some stylized facts p. 81). Given that oil exporters import about the historical development of the (industrial) goods and services predom- main bilateral exchange rates to the inantly and increasingly from Europe U.S. dollar and of crude oil prices. Sec- and Asia rather than the U.S.A. (e.g. tion 2 introduces a review of the theo- Ruiz-Perez and Vilarrubia, 2006) and retical and empirical literature on the diversify their investment away from link between these variables and dis- U.S. dollar-denominated assets (BIS, cusses the five hypotheses on the pre- MONETARY POLICY & THE ECONOMY Q4/08 103
Crude Oil Prices and the USD/EUR Exchange Rate sumed negative (causal) relationship whole sample of data yields a corre- between exchange rates and oil mar- lation coefficient of –0.64, both sign kets. In section 3 we present our fore- and size of this correlation vary quite casting exercise; section 4 concludes. substantially across the four different periods – a result which is also con- 1 A Short Contemporary History firmed by rolling correlation exercises. of Oil Prices and the The first period under observation U.S. Dollar Exchange Rate (1950 to 1970) coincides with the In post-war economic history (1950 to Bretton Woods system of fixed ex- 2007) we can roughly distinguish four change rates, which was introduced in periods in the relationship between oil 1946. The commitment to maintain a prices and the (synthetic) USD/EUR fixed conversion rate of the U.S. dollar exchange rate. Chart 1 shows annual to gold created a world dollar standard time series of U.S. crude oil import (McKinnon, 2005), i.e. all other ex- prices and nominal USD/EUR ex- change rates were anchored to the change rates (a synthetic euro is used (gold) dollar. During this golden age for the period prior to 1999 while (Marglin and Schor, 1990) of low infla- for the period prior to 1978, the tion, low interest rates and high growth, Deutsche mark is converted into syn- crude oil prices remained remarkably thetic euro). stable and low. The price formation The four different periods are easily process took place under the control of discernable by the two variables’ vary- the so-called Seven Sisters, i.e. the seven ing volatility and their degree of co- international oil companies that domi- movement. Interestingly, these periods nated mid-20th century oil production, coincide with important regime shifts refinement and distribution. in both oil and money markets. The dis- This period of extraordinary stabil- tinction of the periods is also reflected ity was followed by an episode of rup- by changing correlations between crude ture between 1971 and 1984, which is oil prices and nominal USD/EUR usually associated with the first and exchange rates (table 1). While the second oil price shocks of 1973 and Chart 1 USD Exchange Rate and Crude Oil Prices 1950 to 2007 (annual change) USD EUR/USD 70 1.80 60 1.60 50 1.40 40 1.20 30 1.00 20 10 0.80 0 0.60 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 USD per barrel crude oil (left-hand scale) EUR/USD exchange rate (right-hand scale)1 Source: EIA, BIS, Bloomberg, www.history.ucsb.edu. 1 Before 1978: synthetic EUR values (converted DEM). 104 MONETARY POLICY & THE ECONOMY Q4/08
Crude Oil Prices and the USD/EUR Exchange Rate Table 1 Four Periods of Correlation between U.S. Dollar Exchange Rates and Oil Prices Period Time spread Key element Volatility Correlation 1 1950 to 1970 Bretton Woods System low –0.62 2 1971 to 1984 Oil supply shocks I and II high –0.18 3 1985 to 1998 OPEC collapse medium +0.44 4 1999 to 2007 Emerging market demand and tight supply high –0.80 Source: OeNB. 1979, respectively. The so-called Nixon regain strength due to the so-called shock (e.g. Kuroda, 2004) had occurred Volcker shock. By limiting money supply on August 15, 1971, i.e. even before and abandoning interest rate targets, the first oil price shock, when U.S. the chairman of the Federal Reserve president Richard Nixon announced System, Paul Volcker, successfully the discontinuation of gold convertibil- trimmed down inflation by more than ity of the U.S. dollar given the deterio- 10 percentage points in two years – a rating U.S. balance of payments. This measure which entailed a significant move resulted in a steep depreciation of recession, however. The negative corre- the value of the U.S. dollar against gold lation between the U.S. dollar exchange and many other currencies, notably the rate and the crude oil price can be Deutsche mark and the Japanese yen. observed until 1985. Since oil was invoiced in U.S. dollars, Between 1985 and 1998 the corre- this implied that oil producers were lation between U.S. dollar exchange receiving fewer revenues at the same rates and oil prices diminished in abso- price of oil. The Organization of the lute terms, while both remained re- Oil Exporting Countries (OPEC) was markably stable (Krichene, 2006). This initially slow in adjusting oil prices to period was characterized by the col- reflect the U.S. dollar’s depreciation. lapse of the oil price and a weak U.S. Only two years later, during the Yom dollar following the Plaza Accord con- Kippur War, OPEC cut its oil produc- cluded by five G-7 countries. Impor- tion and placed an embargo on ship- tant changes took place in the OPEC ments of crude oil to the West. As a which affected its power to exert influ- result the oil price had quadrupled by ence on the oil market. In August 1985, 1974, reaching USD 12 per barrel. The Saudi Arabia gave up its swing producer second oil crisis occurred in the wake strategy (which had involved occasional of the Iranian Revolution, which tem- production cuts in order to stem price porarily shattered oil production in the decreases), linking its oil prices to the country. The subsequent market panic spot market for crude oil and more than and a phased decontrol of oil prices by doubling its extraction quantity in- the Carter administration triggered an- stead. By mid-1986, crude oil prices other boost of crude oil prices over the had dropped to around USD 10 per next 12 months, with prices going up barrel. From then until 1998, oil prices to almost USD 40 per barrel. Subse- remained weak and OPEC’s attempts quently, oil prices moderated slightly to set price targets failed, not least despite the ongoing war between Iran and because rapidly growing spot, forward Iraq, but remained at a high level. In and futures markets brought about parallel, the U.S. dollar started to greater price transparency and inde- MONETARY POLICY & THE ECONOMY Q4/08 105
Crude Oil Prices and the USD/EUR Exchange Rate pendence of oil importing countries led to insufficient supplies. Future sup- from the alleged cartel. ply, however, increasingly became a In September 1985, the Plaza Accord major matter of concern, as global was signed with the aim of devaluing crude oil production did not amplified the U.S. dollar in relation to the for two years in a row and excess de- Japanese yen and Deutsche mark in mand could only be met by natural gas order to help the U.S.A. reduce its liquids (NGL). Given the fact that non- current account deficit and emerge OPEC production is already beyond its from a serious recession. Over the fol- peak, the only hope for meeting increas- lowing two years, coordinated central ing demand rests on the oil production bank intervention in currency markets by OPEC countries. The fact that these caused a depreciation of the U.S. dollar countries are politically instable added against the Japanese yen by more than to the apprehension about future oil 50%. The decline of the U.S. dollar supply. Being in the comfortable posi- exchange rate was slowed by the Louvre tion of a producer of last resort, the Accord, signed by six G-7 countries in OPEC is experiencing a revival of some 1987, but the U.S. currency did not of its market power, as announced pro- recuperate until the middle of the next duction cuts have now again been at decade. least partly effective. Actual and expec- The price of crude oil surged tem- ted oil market fundamentals,3 geopo- porarily in 1990 during the Iraqi occu- litical tensions as well as financial tur- pation of Kuwait, but after the subse- moil – not least due to excess liquid- quent Gulf War crude oil prices declined ity – have given rise to financial almost uninterruptedly, partly squeezed speculation, which in turn has contrib- by transition-induced recession in the uted to an overshooting oil market. former Soviet Union and in Central and At the beginning of the last period, Eastern Europe (Borensztein and Rein- the U.S. dollar was supported by the hart, 1994), reaching their deepest booming U.S. economy. However, from level throughout the Asian Crisis of around 2002 onward – after a short 1997 and 1998. interruption of the oil price hike4 – The last period under review, i.e. the relation between the U.S. dollar the period from 1999 to 2007,2 is exchange rate and oil prices has once marked by an oil price pickup which again become clearly negative. Accu- has been triggered by increasing mulating U.S. external imbalances have demand from emerging markets (in built up pressure on the U.S. dollar, particular from China). Both the failure and the situation has been aggravated of oil producers to anticipate the fast by mounting interest rate differentials rebound of the Asian economies and in comparison to the euro area. Very the low levels of exploration investment recently, however, both the U.S. dollar due to low crude oil prices in the 1990s decline and the oil prices hike have 2 From the present point of view, this period lasted until mid-2008. 3 Additionally, crude oil prices may have been driven by many other factors. As for refining capacity, it should be noticed that unlike common believe the relationship to oil prices is negative such that higher refinery utilization rates reduce crude oil prices. This effect arises from shifts in the production of heavy and light grades of crude oil, leading to changes in price spreads between them and depending on the composition of demand as well as the technical requirements of refining (Kaufmann et al., 2008). 4 This interruption would justify dividing the last period into two shock phases. 106 MONETARY POLICY & THE ECONOMY Q4/08
Crude Oil Prices and the USD/EUR Exchange Rate been partially reversed, as it became channel highlighted by the respective evident, that Europe and the rest of the theory, the link may either be positive world would not be able to decouple or negative or may change from one pe- from the economic slump in the United riod to the other. Five possible channels States. of a negative causal relation between As this short overview suggests, any the external value of the U.S. dollar meaningful interpretation of data be- and crude oil prices can be put forward havior has to take into account geopo- (e.g. Cheng, 2008). litical and historical economic events. Notwithstanding the difficulties of 2.1 Purchasing Power Channel abstracting from these facts, some the- To the extent that oil-exporting coun- ories of a more general nature have tries aim to stabilize the purchasing already been put forward. power of their (U.S. dollar) export rev- enues in terms of their (predominantly 2 Theoretical Models of the Oil euro-denominated) imports, changes Price – Exchange Rate Link and in the U.S. dollar/euro (USD/EUR) Empirical Evidence exchange rate may be mirrored in oil The exchange rate/oil price link has exporters’ pricing behavior5 (Amuzegar, been defined as a kind of natural rela- 1978). Following up on the role of the tionship by Mundell, 2002, p. 1: “[t]here U.S. dollar as a numeraire of standard is a definite link between monetary policies, commodities (U.S. dollar commodities), exchange rates and commodity prices (…)”. a change in U.S. dollar exchange rates This view acknowledges the simple alters the terms of trade between any truth that changes in prices might also pair of countries. The extent of this reflect changes in their numeraire. change depends on the proportion of With the gold-dollar standard in place, “dollar goods” relative to “non-U.S. it was logical to price and quote homog- dollar goods” in these countries’ trade enous goods like commodities in U.S. structure (Schulmeister, 2000). Since dollars. Later, under a flexible exchange the difference between the export and rate regime, markets continued to stick import share of dollar goods is greatest to the U.S. dollar, partly because having for oil-exporting countries, their in- only one reference and vehicle currency come position is most strongly affected is efficient. Yet, the extreme instability by U.S. dollar exchange rate fluctua- of the external value of the U.S. dollar tions. Hence, they have an incentive to has translated into U.S. dollar prices of react to U.S. dollar depreciation by commodities such as crude oil. The increasing export prices.6 underlying causes of this apparent link The plausibility of this purchasing between the commodity price cycle power channel hinges on at least three and the U.S. dollar cycle, however, are conditions: First, oil exporters have a controversial. These cycles may mutu- certain degree of price-setting capacity. ally affect each other or be both caused Second, oil exporters receive a substan- by common factors. Depending on the tial share of their imports from Europe 5 Although it is often the case that the literature refers to the price-setting behavior of oil exporters, it should be noted that the OPEC, as of 1986, has not tried to set prices directly, but followed a quantity strategy which indirectly influenced the market clearing price. 6 Note that their reaction might be asymmetric, as they tend to tolerate the U.S. dollar’s appreciation rather than depreciation. MONETARY POLICY & THE ECONOMY Q4/08 107
Crude Oil Prices and the USD/EUR Exchange Rate (in particular from euro area coun- Perhaps the most accurate way to tries). Third, for good reasons, oil in- describe the market has been under- voicing is conducted in U.S. dollars. taken by Yousefi and Wirjanto (2005). We will briefly examine evidence on They consider a model of oligopolistic each of these three conditions. rivalry among oil-exporting countries As to the first condition, the mar- with a partial sharing of a world oil ket for crude oil is often described as a market segmented by quality differ- cartel, which is at best an oversimpli- ences (sweet vs. sour, heavy vs. light, fication (Krugman, 2000).7 Indeed, the etc.). In each segment each member coun- concurrence of declining production try enjoys a certain degree of market with plummeting prices during the power due to non-homogenous commod- early 1980s and the subsequent reversal ities (imperfect substitutes). This results of this behavior in both time series are in Bertrand competition with incomplete not characteristic of a cartelized mar- price equalization and Saudi Arabia ket (Yousefi and Wirjanto, 2005). – by far the biggest OPEC oil producer Certainly, members of the OPEC do with about one-third of OPEC produc- exert some market power, but the ex- tion – displaying price leadership. tent of it varies dramatically over time As to the second condition, the depending on general market condi- asymmetry of the trade structure of tions. With soaring demand from China oil-exporting economies is presented and other emerging economies as well in table 2. While the fact that oil is as gradually depleting sources in non- invoiced in U.S. dollars first implies OPEC oil-producing countries, OPEC that virtually all exports are going to has arguably regained some price-set- the U.S. dollar area, the U.S. dollar ting capacity. In 2006 OPEC’s 13 mem- plays only a marginal role with respect ber countries accounted for 55% of to oil exporters’ imports. In particular world crude oil exports, 45% of world the EU (and the euro area) is the most oil production and about 78% of the important source region for consump- world’s oil reserves. tion and investment goods in exchange for petrodollars.8 Table 2 Geographical Trading Patterns of Ten Major Oil Exporters (2005)1 U.S.A. Euro area EU Asia Share in % Export destinations 13.9 27.4 38.7 25.6 Import sources 6.8 29.2 41.9 25.4 Source: ECB (2007). 1 Algeria, Iran, Kuwait, Libya, Nigeria, Norway, Russia, Saudi Arabia, UAE and Venezuela. 7 Krugman (2000) refers to an idea of multiple equilibria developed by Cremer and Isfahani (1991). According to this, the fact that oil is an exhaustible resource means that not extracting it is a form of investment. For a differ- ent explanation, see Rauscher (1992). 8 Note that in this sample Russia and Norway are included, which compared to OPEC have even closer ties to the EU than to Asia. According to Mazraati (2005), average import shares of OPEC between 1970 and 2004 have been 28.82% from the euro area and 13.45% from the U.S.A. 108 MONETARY POLICY & THE ECONOMY Q4/08
Crude Oil Prices and the USD/EUR Exchange Rate Eventually, such asymmetry should tion and currency fluctuations (OPEC, translate into the terms of trade.9 2006).10 Half of this basket is made up Already in 1972 certain OPEC mem- by the euro (46.4%; Mazraati, 2005). bers and international oil companies We take this high weight as justifi- concluded the Geneva I Agreement, which cation for simplifying our empirical ex- introduced quarterly adjustments to ercise by using the USD/EUR exchange posted prices to take account of rate as a proxy to nominal effective exchange rate changes. They set up an exchange rates. Over time, however, index which later has changed to an the share of the euro area within all import-weighted index, the present OPEC imports has decreased, as shown modified Geneva I + U.S. dollar currency in chart 3, in favor of developing and basket, which accounts for both infla- emerging economies. As to the third condition, oil expor- Chart 2 ters face three interrelated currency Geneva I + USD Currency Basket choices: invoicing, recycling of oil rev- 1998 to 2002 enues and pegging. Mileva and Siegfried Shares of currencies (2007) explain the almost universal use (reflecting import weights) of the U.S. dollar in invoicing11 petro- % leum by the fact that oil is a homo- 2.9 geneous good traded in commodity 10.1 exchanges. The initial decision to in- voice in U.S. dollars has possibly to do with the U.S.A.’s reputation of a stable 15.3 economy and the depth of its finan- 46.4 cial markets, but is also built on politi- cal grounds. In the mid-1970s, Saudi Arabia was highly influential in ensur- ing that oil-prices were set in U.S. dol- lars.12 Since then, the latter member states of the Gulf Cooperation Council 25.3 (GCC) have supported the value of Swiss franc the U.S. dollar by invoicing oil in U.S. Euro U.S. dollar dollars and by investing in U.S. dollar Japanese yen Pound Sterling reserves and securities. Despite their nervousness about U.S. imbalances and Source: Mazraati (2005). the declining value of U.S. dollar 9 Mazraati (2005) calculated that between 1970 and 2004 the loss in purchasing power of OPEC oil revenues through the U.S. dollar’s depreciation had been significant (–15.6%), but smaller than the loss through inflation (–57.4%). Yet these two effects are difficult to disentangle as virtually all oil-producing economies with undiver- sified economies and U.S. dollar-pegged currencies display an inverse relationship between the value of the U.S. dollar and inflation (Alhajji, 2004). 10 Indeed, for some time OPEC used currency variations in the Geneva basket to justify oil price increases; although it is unclear to what extend this actually played a role. 11 Attempts to shift to euro invoicing have been made by Iran, Iraq and Venezuela. 12 In 1975 a U.S.-Saudi deal to recycle Saudi wealth into U.S. bonds was complemented by a subsequent arrange- ment to invoice oil in U.S. dollars. Saudi Arabia used its OPEC influence to persuade the other members to sell OPEC oil in U.S. dollars, in exchange for enhanced power in the IMF and military protection (Momani, 2006). MONETARY POLICY & THE ECONOMY Q4/08 109
Crude Oil Prices and the USD/EUR Exchange Rate Chart 3 Shares in OPEC Imports (without intra-OPEC Trade) % of total imports 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 Euro area United Kingdom Switzerland U.S.A. Japan Rest of the world Source: IMF. reserves, GCC oil exporters have a big favor of a reorientation of their econo- stake in the U.S. economy (Momani, mies away from the U.S. dollar toward 2006). Almost all oil-exporting coun- the euro.14 Nevertheless, the dominant tries, and in particular, the GCC coun- role of the U.S. dollar as invoice, invest- tries have their exchange rates either ment and anchor currency seems to be formally pegged or tightly oriented to unchallenged so far despite the fact that the U.S. dollar (ECB, 2007). They it has pushed oil exporters into a mon- regard dollarization as beneficial given etary dilemma and in conflict with their reliance on the export of a single their own development strategies. As U.S. dollar-priced commodity, but also long as feasible alternatives are not in because it may lower financing costs, sight,15 the current OPEC strategy of help attract foreign investment and sup- dollarization and oil price stabilization port macroeconomic stability.13 How- proves reasonable. ever, a decline in the value of U.S. dol- lars and expansionary monetary policy 2.2 Local Price Channel in the United States adds to the infla- Apart from the described supply-side tionary pressure in oil-exporting coun- purchasing power channel,16 there is tries already mounting due to soaring arguably also a demand-side local price oil prices. Additionally, enhanced trade channel at work. According to Austvik ties with Europe and the envisaged (1987), fluctuations in the exchange reduction of oil dependence speak in rate of the U.S. dollar create disequi- 13 Furthermore, dollarization facilitates the transition of the GCC countries into a currency union by 2010, which is to be an instrument to integrate and to diversify the economies of the region. The decision to establish a common currency was taken at the foundation of the GCC in 1981. The official adoption of the U.S. dollar as a common basis was agreed in 2001. Only after its actual introduction, the new currency may be either anchored to the euro, a currency basket, or floating freely (BIS, 2003). 14 OPEC Secretary-General Abdalla El-Badri announced recently, “Maybe we can price the oil in the euro. It can be done, but it will take time.” (www.gulfnews.com/business/Oil_and_Gas/10188508.html; published on February 9, 2008). 15 Frankel (2006) proposed a peg to oil export prices, which would possibly exacerbate volatility. Mundell (2002) proposed invoicing in special drawing rights. 16 Note that Alhajji (2004) also observes that the U.S. dollar’s depreciation reduces activities in drilling activities in Europe and the Middle East. 110 MONETARY POLICY & THE ECONOMY Q4/08
Crude Oil Prices and the USD/EUR Exchange Rate libria in the market for crude oil. The use of the presumed anti-cyclical per- U.S. dollar’s depreciation makes petrol formance of commodity futures. In the less expensive for consumers in non- context of this study it is only impor- U.S. dollar regions (in local currency), tant to note that activity in West Texas thereby increasing their commodity Intermediate (WTI) future contracts demand, which eventually causes adjust- has grown strikingly since 2000. ments in the oil price denominated in Between January 2004 and June 2008 U.S. dollars. Using annual BP data the number of open interest contracts from between 1965 and 2007, we dis- across all relevant contract types traded cover as a first indication of this channel on the New York Mercantile Exchange a highly negative correlation (–0.81) be- (NYMEX) alone more than tripled tween European demand for oil prod- from around 900,000 to more than ucts and the USD/EUR exchange rate. 2.9 million. Yet empirical evidence suggests that the causality goes rather 2.3 Investment Channel from oil future price changes to changes In addition, an asset channel is put in in contract positions than the reverse motion, as a falling U.S. dollar reduces (ITF, 2008). the returns on U.S. dollar-denomina- ted financial assets in foreign currencies, 2.4 Monetary Policy Channel hence increasing the attractiveness of Co-movements could also evolve by a oil and other commodities as a class of monetary channel, as the U.S. dollar’s alternative assets to foreign investors. depreciation entails monetary easing Furthermore their attractiveness as a elsewhere, including oil-producing hedge against inflation rises too, since countries with currencies pegged to the U.S. dollar’s depreciation raises the U.S. dollar. In turn, lower interest risks of inflationary pressures in the rates increase liquidity, thereby stimu- United States. This is reminiscent of lating demand, together with that for the topical debate over the extent to oil (Cheng, 2008). This channel is which contemporary oil price develop- evidenced by the fact that currently ments are driven by market speculation most of the growth in global crude oil rather than fundamentals. Krugman demand comes from China and the (2008) speaks about an “oil nonbubble.” Middle East, both known for having He argues that “the only way specula- their currencies anchored to the tion can have a persistent effect on oil U.S. dollar. Similarly, one could argue prices is if it leads to physical hoarding,” that both relative price developments which he cannot discern. Yet, Stevans (oil price and exchange rate) may have and Sessions (2008) counter, “(…) common causes. Most prominently, there is empirical evidence of hoarding the hypotheses that oil and other com- in the crude oil market: both oil stocks modity price developments are influ- and futures prices are positively corre- enced by interest rates (Frankel, 2006) lated with each other.” The debate is in combination with the theory of not concluded yet, not least because it (uncovered) interest rate parity of is difficult to distinguish between spec- exchange rates would allow such a ulation, which exploits rather short- rationalization. term volatility, and hedging activity with the aim of diversifying portfolios, 2.5 Currency Market Channel insuring oil-dependent industries Finally, a currency market channel may be against price-related risks and making at work as well, since foreign exchange MONETARY POLICY & THE ECONOMY Q4/08 111
Crude Oil Prices and the USD/EUR Exchange Rate Chart 4 USD Federal Funds Rate and Crude Oil Price 1971 to 2007 (annual change) USD % 70 18.0 16.0 60 14.0 50 12.0 40 10.0 30 8.0 6.0 20 4.0 10 2.0 0 0.0 1971 1976 1981 1986 1991 1996 2001 2006 USD per barrel crude oil (left-hand scale) Federal funds target rate (right-hand scale) Source: EIA, Thomson Reuters. markets are possibly more efficient than invested in U.S. dollar assets, but it oil markets and hence anticipate devel- might turn negative in the long run opments in the real economy that affect since over time OPEC’s spending on the demand for and supply of oil (Chen manufactured products rises, and pref- et al., 2008). The causality of this last erably these imports come from other channel appears to go from the U.S. countries than the United States. Exten- dollar to oil prices, while it is actually sions of this model by Krugman (1984) underlying a relation which runs in the deliver similar outcomes, namely that opposite direction. In this sense, hypo- an oil shock affects all countries, and its theses on a negative relation in which exchange rate effects arise from asym- oil impacts the U.S. dollar might com- metries between countries. The same plement rather than substitute the hypo- asymmetries determine the outcome of theses on a reverse direction of causal- the above-mentioned purchasing power ity from the U.S. dollar to oil, which channel of the reversed causality. we prefer here. Ultimately the question concerning One of the above-mentioned chan- which one of these channels domina- nels may dominate the relationship, tes should be approached empirically. which does not exclude the influence Table 3 collects the most relevant pieces of even (temporarily) contradictory of the empirical literature on the forces. Krugman (1980), for instance, exchange rate-oil price link; they dis- proposed a three-country model where play a great variety of estimation results the direction of the effect depends on due to differences in theoretical con- a comparison of balance of payment cepts, data definition and temporal effects of higher oil prices with those of delimitation.17 Over time, the negative petrodollar recycling. Initially the rela- relation between the U.S. dollar and tion would be positive as oil profits are the oil price, driven by the exchange 17 One noticeable detail is that most studies use real instead of nominal data. However, we regard nominal data as more appropriate since oil prices contribute directly and indirectly via other input costs, such as energy or other commodities, to inflation. Thus, inflation adjustment removes some important information of this relative price. Real exchange rates, which are sometimes used as well, mask the fact that exchange rate and inflation are inter- dependent. 112 MONETARY POLICY & THE ECONOMY Q4/08
Crude Oil Prices and the USD/EUR Exchange Rate Table 3 Selection of Studies on the Relationship between Crude Oil Prices and U.S. Dollar Exchange Rates Exchange rate Study Direction Causality Theory Model Period Oil data Method data Cheng, 2008 Short- and USD ➝ oil Purchasing Demand-sup- 1980–2007 NEER and Average Dynamic long-term power, local ply framework REER USD petroleum ordinary least negative price, asset, (Borensztein/ spot price squares (except 1980s) and monetary Reinhart, channel 1994) Bénassy- Cointegration; Real oil ➝ real China impacts Four-country 1974–2004 REER USD Real market Cointegration Quéré et al., long-term USD via USD peg model price crude 2005 positive, but Causality and energy- (Krugman, petroleum negative from reversal as of intensive 1980): U.S.A., 2002 on 2002 growth China, OPEC (1980–2004) (robustness VECM (U.S. dollar EUR-USD) Granger test bloc); EU Krichene, Cointegra- USD ➝ oil Purchasing Simultane- 1970–2004 NEER USD IMF crude oil VAR 2005 tion, long-and power, local ous equation price index short-term price channel model (SEM), negative structural impact model and interest rates and NEER Yousefi and Negative Real USD Purchasing Incomplete FX 1989– 1999 REER USD Monthly spot OLS Wirjanto, export price ➝ oil power of pass-through, index prices of estimation 2005 elasticity oil revenues oligopolistic 4 OPEC with standard channel rivalry of members error OPEC correction Yousefi and Negative USD ➝ oil Purchasing Partial 1989–1999 REER USD WTI, Brent, Hansen’s Wirjanto, correlation power of market-sharing (price adjusted OPEC and GMM, perfect 2004 oil revenues model, price Pmcdi + Pbdi) monthly spot correlation channel; leadership prices Incomplete Saudi Arabia exchange rate pass-through Amano and Positively Oil ➝ Real oil price Single equa- 1972–1992 REER USD Real WTI Dynamic van Norden, cointegrated exchange rate reflects terms tion error simulations 1998 of trade correction shocks model Source: OeNB. Note: NEER: Nominal effective exchange rate; REER: Real effective exchange rate; WTI: West Texas Intermediate; VAR: Vector autoregression; VECM: Vector error correction- model; OLS: Ordinary least squares. rate, gets increasing support (Cheng, The impact of oil prices on ex- 2008; Krichene, 2005; Yousefi and change rates of currencies other than Wirjanto, 2005). Still, a considerable the U.S. dollar has at least partly been group of authors disagrees (Amano confirmed by various researchers and van Norden, 1998; Bénassy-Quéré (Akram, 2004; Chen and Chen, 2007; et al., 2005; Schimmel, 2008). Habib and Kalamova, 2007; Korhonen MONETARY POLICY & THE ECONOMY Q4/08 113
Crude Oil Prices and the USD/EUR Exchange Rate and Juurikkala, 2007). Typically, such including changes in the exchange rate, studies focus on currencies of oil-ex- its determinants and oil prices, as well porting countries, where the nexus as a vector error correction (VEC) arises more directly than in the case of model for these variables. In the case of the U.S. dollar. The apparent differ- the VAR and VEC models, the specifi- ence in terms of direction of causality cation can be interpreted as a monetary between these results and most studies model of exchange rate determination (including ours) on the U.S. dollar oil augmented with an oil price variable relation indicate that the U.S. dollar (e.g. Frenkel, 1976; Meese and Rogoff, could be an exception due to its role as 1983; MacDonald and Taylor, 1992 and the oil invoicing currency. 1994), where the exchange rate is as- Recently, related studies on a more sumed to be determined by changes in general link between exchange rates the relative money supply, output and and commodity prices have delivered interest rate changes in the U.S.A. and important results. In the case of freely the euro area. floating commodity currencies, there For both economies, the data for seems to be more evidence that com- money supply refer to M1, production modities are affected by currencies is proxied by the industrial production rather than vice versa (Chen et al., 2008; index and we use the 1-month money Clements and Fry, 2006). A broader, market rate as the relevant interest rate. less selective sample of commodity cur- The USD/EUR exchange rate prior to rencies, however, suggests the opposite 1999 refers to the synthetic euro and conclusion (Cashin et al., 2004). the nominal oil price is U.S. dollar per barrel (West Texas Intermediate). All 3 The U.S. Dollar Exchange Rate data are of monthly frequency, cover- and Oil Prices: A Forecasting ing the period January 1983 to Decem- Exercise ber 2007 and stem from Datastream In this section we perform a simple with the exception of oil price data, forecasting exercise aimed at evaluating whose source is the Energy Informa- whether changes in the USD/EUR tion Administration.19 exchange rate contain information The two competing models are about future changes in oil prices.18 For given by the following specifications, that purpose we compare the predic- p tions of a simple autoregressive (AR) Δpt = φ0 + ∑ φ Δp k t −k + εt (1) model on oil price changes with those k =1 of a vector autoregressive (VAR) model, and 18 There are two reasons for the use of an out-of-sample approach. On the one hand, nesting all possible links in a single theoretical (structural) model, which would be needed to test the different channels properly, is a hopeless aim. This would imply developing a fully-fledged model for the whole world, whose assumptions could be just as readily criticized as the concentration on small partially reduced models such as the one we use here. This problem is also magnified by the fact that, empirically, some of the channels may be observationally equivalent. On the other hand, the focus on out-of-sample predictability may be seen as an extra value added of this study, in the sense that most of the literature concentrates on in-sample correlations which may or may not contain important information for prediction. 19 We chose monthly data in order to limit white noise associated with higher frequencies and to better focus on fundamental drivers of data movements. We use nominal data not least because real data would enter the con- sumer price index which is endogenous to oil prices and exchange rates. Our series of interest is the front-month contract price of barrel of West Texas Intermediate (WTI) which is one of the three marker crudes (together with Brent and Dubai) whose prices are strongly linked to each other. 114 MONETARY POLICY & THE ECONOMY Q4/08
Crude Oil Prices and the USD/EUR Exchange Rate p years (36 months) ahead. Measures of Δvt = Θ 0 + ∑ Θ k Δvt − k + u t (2) forecasting error are computed for the k =1 predictions by using the actually real- ized oil prices at the different forecast- where vt = (pt et mt yt it ), pt = ln(pt ), et = ing horizons. The observation corre- ln(et ), mt = ln(Mt,US /Mt,EUR ), yt = ln(Yt,US / sponding to January 1997 is added to Yt,EUR ), it = (rt,US – rt,EUR ) and et = ln(et ), the estimation sample, the models are where pt is the oil price, Mt is money re-estimated (after choosing a poten- supply, Yt is output, rt is the interest rate tially new optimal lag length) and the and et is the nominal USD/EUR ex- procedure described above is repeated change rate. Θ0 is a 5-dimensional vec- for this new in-sample period. This tor of intercept terms and Θk are 5×5 procedure is iterated until no usable matrices of parameters. The error term out-of-sample observations are left. εt is assumed to be a white noise process We compute two measures of fore- with constant variance σ2, and ut = (u1t casting accuracy: u 2t u 3t u4t u 5t ) is assumed to be an iid a) The root mean squared error vector process with zero mean and a (RMSE), given by constant variance-covariance matrix Σ. Since there is evidence of a unit root 1 T +h+ N h ∑( ) 2 for all variables in the vector v, a poten- RMSE (h ) = pn − pn (4) N n =T + h tial specification relating these variables would be a vector error correction where pht is the forecast for pt obtained (VEC) model, where there is an adjust- by the model with data ranging up to ment in the long run to a cointegration t–h, and N is the number of out-of-sam- relationship given by a linear function ple forecasts carried out. Root mean relating the covariates of the model, squared errors are computed for fore- p casting horizons (h), ranging from one Δvt = Γ 0 + ∑ Γ Δv k t −k + αβ ' vt −1 + u t (3) month ahead to 36 months ahead. b) The direction-of-change (DOC) k =1 statistic, defined as the number of where β is the (column) cointegrating correctly forecast changes in the oil vector, which defines the long-run price for forecasting horizon h equilibrium among the variables of the divided by the total size of the fore- system, given by β’vt, and α is a (column) casting sample for that forecasting vector capturing the adjustment speed horizon. This measure describes the of each one of the components of vt. model’s ability of correctly forecast- The forecasting exercise is carried ing the direction of change of the oil out as follows. The models given by (1), price. (2) and (3) are estimated using monthly If two models deliver forecasts of data from January 1983 to December different quality (as measured for in- 1996 and choosing the optimal lag stance by the RMSE), the question length ( p in the specifications above) by arises if the “better” model performs minimizing the Bayesian information significantly better than the “worse” criterion (BIC) for lag lengths one to model in statistical terms. In order to twelve. With the estimated models, evaluate the statistical significance of out-of-sample forecasts for the oil price differences in RMSE, we compute the are produced for forecasting horizons Diebold-Mariano test. The Diebold- ranging from one month ahead to three Mariano test (Diebold and Mariano, MONETARY POLICY & THE ECONOMY Q4/08 115
Crude Oil Prices and the USD/EUR Exchange Rate 1995 henceforth, DM) is an asymptotic significance is presented in the table in test for the null hypothesis of equal pre- the form of asterisks. Some interesting dictive accuracy of two models. For a results can be read from table 4. In given forecasting horizon h, the null terms of RMSE, models including in- hypothesis in the DM test is that formation on the exchange rate and its determinants perform better than the dn = E [ g(e1n ) − g(e2 n )] = 0 (5) benchmark AR model for forecasting horizons up to one year ahead and over where e1n is the forecasting error pro- 18 months ahead. For short-term fore- duced by model 1 when forecasting pt, casts the VAR model, which abstracts e2n is defined analogously for model 2 away from the existence of a long-run and g(z) is a loss function associated to relationship linking the variables in the the forecast error. In our case, the loss VAR structure, is the specification that function is a quadratic one, so that performs best, obtaining forecasts g(z) = z2 . The DM test is based on the which are significantly better than the observed average forecast error differ- benchmark model (as measured by the ence, d The DM test statistic is given by DM test statistic) in forecasting hori- zons ranging up to six months ahead. S1 = [Vˆ (d )]−1/ 2 d (6) The VEC model performs best for rela- tively long forecasting horizons and ob- V̂ (d ) is an estimate of the asymptotic tains significantly better forecasts than variance of d, given by the AR benchmark at forecasting hori- zons of more than two and a half years 1⎛ h −1 ⎞ N⎝ ∑ Vˆ (d ) = ⎜ γˆ0 + 2 γˆ k ⎟ ⎠ (7) ahead. k =1 The results concerning the DOC where γ̂k is the k-th order sample auto- statistic speak clearly for the inclusion covariance of the forecasting error dif- of information on the exchange rate ference series. The asymptotic distribu- when forecasting oil prices. The best- tion of S1 is standard normal, so tests performing model according to this for equality of predictive accuracy be- criterion is the VAR model for rela- tween different models can be easily tively short forecasting horizons (up to carried out. Although the DM test has nine months ahead) and the VEC model become standard in forecasting evalua- for longer forecasting horizons. The tion research, this test methodology is supremacy of the models including in- not free of criticism. For a recent criti- formation on the exchange rate and its cal assessment to testing predictive determinants when forecasting the accuracy using the DM test statistic see direction of change of the oil price is Kunst (2003). systematic and robust for all forecasting Table 4 presents the results of the horizons considered. forecasting exercise described above. As a robustness check we also per- The results corresponding to the best formed the forecasting exercise using models in terms of forecasting accuracy exclusively bivariate time series models are presented in bold characters. For formed by the oil price and the exchange each forecasting horizon in which the rate, that is, without controlling for the VAR and/or VEC model performs potential determinants of the exchange better than the benchmark AR model rate. The results of this exercise are we carried out a DM test for equal fore- presented in table 5, and they reinforce casting accuracy; the result in terms of those found with the larger VAR models. 116 MONETARY POLICY & THE ECONOMY Q4/08
Crude Oil Prices and the USD/EUR Exchange Rate Table 4 Results of the Forecasting Exercise: Multivariate Time Series Models Months AR model VAR model VEC model Out-of-sample ahead observations RMSE DOC RMSE DOC RMSE DOC 1 0.084 0.472 0.082* 0.509 0.084 0.491 108 3 0.164 0.453 0.152* 0.528 0.171 0.481 106 6 0.242 0.379 0.223* 0.515 0.265 0.447 103 9 0.307 0.410 0.295 0.490 0.345 0.490 100 12 0.370 0.371 0.365 0.392 0.407 0.474 97 15 0.428 0.362 0.428 0.340 0.451 0.511 94 18 0.466 0.418 0.471 0.308 0.478 0.516 91 21 0.494 0.398 0.505 0.284 0.491 0.523 88 24 0.516 0.388 0.532 0.165 0.492 0.565 85 27 0.522 0.383 0.540 0.198 0.483 0.617 82 30 0.532 0.316 0.551 0.139 0.483 0.544 79 33 0.547 0.250 0.562 0.145 0.482* 0.539 76 36 0.569 0.151 0.581 0.123 0.486** 0.493 73 Source: OeNB. Note: (*) refer to the significance level of the Diebold-Mariano test statistic of the corresponding model against the AR model. * (**) refers to significance at the 10% (5%) significance level. The best models for each forecasting horizon are in bold font. Table 5 Results of the Forecasting Exercise: Bivariate Time Series Models Months AR model VAR model VEC model Out-of-sample ahead observations RMSE DOC RMSE DOC RMSE DOC 1 0.084 0.472 0.081* 0.528 0.084 0.472 108 3 0.164 0.453 0.151* 0.566 0.176 0.519 106 6 0.242 0.379 0.219 0.563 0.280 0.437 103 9 0.307 0.410 0.291 0.550 0.365 0.480 100 12 0.370 0.371 0.360 0.433 0.423 0.464 97 15 0.428 0.362 0.421 0.362 0.461 0.500 94 18 0.466 0.418 0.462 0.352 0.483 0.505 91 21 0.494 0.398 0.495 0.318 0.490 0.534 88 24 0.516 0.388 0.521 0.224 0.486 0.576 85 27 0.522 0.383 0.527 0.235 0.474 0.630 82 30 0.532 0.316 0.537 0.215 0.473 0.544 79 33 0.547 0.250 0.547 0.197 0.470* 0.539 76 36 0.569 0.151 0.565 0.164 0.473** 0.493 73 Source: OeNB. Note: (*) refer to the significance level of the Diebold-Mariano test statistic of the corresponding model against the AR model. * (**) refers to significance at the 10% (5%) significance level. The best models for each forecasting horizon are in bold font. In the short run, the VAR model exchange rate and the oil price which including the exchange rate forecasts significantly beats the alternative speci- significantly better than the simple fications. These results thus offer extra autoregressive benchmark, while in the evidence concerning the fact that the long run it is the VEC model with the USD/EUR exchange rate contains in- MONETARY POLICY & THE ECONOMY Q4/08 117
Crude Oil Prices and the USD/EUR Exchange Rate formation about the future develop- form of pertinent questions. Given the ment of oil prices. vulnerability of oil prices to monetary In a preliminary analysis, we ran shocks, should Taylor-like rules explic- Granger causality tests between changes itly include crude price volatility in the exchange rate and the oil price in (Krichene, 2005)? To what extent is a the framework of a bivariate VAR in stable U.S. dollar a prerequisite for first differences in order to grasp the stable oil prices? Would exchange rate existing causality links between these flexibility of oil exporters be a remedy two variables. The results are relatively or an amplifier of global imbalances? inconclusive in this respect: there is What effect would a hard landing marginal evidence of causality running scenario of the U.S. dollar have on oil from the exchange rate to the oil price prices? Is there an alternative to the if VAR models of lag length higher U.S. dollar as invoicing, reserve and than six are used. However, the opti- anchor currency? How should an mal lag length for the bivariate VAR orderly replacement best be managed? model as chosen by the BIC for the And will with euro-, yuan- or basket- complete sample is equal to one. At this denominated oil prices the stagflation- lag length there is no statistical evi- ary effects of oil price shocks be reduced dence of causality links between the two (Wohltmann and Winkler, 2005)? variables.20 Future research should concentrate on modeling and testing the five chan- 4 Concluding Remarks nels of the U.S. dollar-oil nexus. Non- This paper provides evidence for the linearity and asymmetries in the rela- fact that exchange rates do matter in tion (Crespo Cuaresma et al., 2007), as forecasting commodity prices. While, well as the systematic exploitation of both from a theoretical perspective and the cyclical component of oil price from simple Granger-causality tests, changes (see Rauscher, 1992, for a the direction of causality is unclear, we theoretical explanation and Crespo show that exchange rate information Cuaresma et al., 2007, for a recent em- significantly improves oil price fore- pirical application) could be explored. casts. The negative correlation of these The robustness of the forecasting mod- two variables is ascribed to five possible els should be checked further in terms channels: a supply-side purchasing of alternative oil data sets, diverse fre- power channel, a demand-side local quency or trade weighted exchange price channel, an asset market invest- rates. Making an explicit distinction ment channel, a monetary policy re- between supply and demand shocks gime channel and a currency market may also shed more light on the nature efficiency channel. of the relationship between oil prices As to the political implications of and exchange rates (Kilian and Park, our results, we prefer to state those in 2007). 20 Detailed results of the causality analysis are available from the authors upon request. 118 MONETARY POLICY & THE ECONOMY Q4/08
Crude Oil Prices and the USD/EUR Exchange Rate References Akram, Q. F. 2004. Oil Prices and Exchange Rates: Norwegian Evidence. In: The Econometrics Journal 7. 476–504. Alhajji, A. F. 2004. The Impact of Dollar Devaluation on the World Oil Industry: Do Exchange Rates Matter? Middle East Economic Survey XLVII. Amano, R. A. and S. van Norden. 1998. Oil Prices and the Rise and Fall of the US Real Exchange Rate. In: Journal of International Money and Finance 17. 299–316. Amuzegar, J. 1978. OPEC and the Dollar Dilemma. In: Foreign Affairs 56. 740–750. Austvik, O. G. 1987. Oil Prices and the Dollar Dilemma. OPEC Review 4. Bénassy-Quéré, A., V. Mignon and A. Penot. 2005. China and the Relationship between the Oil Price and the Dollar. CEPII Working Paper. BIS. 2003. Regional Currency Areas and the Use of Foreign Currencies. BIS Paper 17. Bank for International Settlements. Basel. BIS. 2006. BIS Quarterly Review. Bank for International Settlements. Basel. Borensztein, E. and C. M. Reinhart. 1994. The Macroeconomic Determinants of Com- modity Prices. Working Paper. Cashin, P., L. F. Cespedes and R. Sahay. 2004. Commodity Currencies and the Real Exchange Rate. In: Journal of Development Economics 75. 239–268. Chen, S.-S. and H.-C. Chen. 2007. Oil Prices and Real Exchange Rates. In: Energy Economics 29. 390–404. Chen, Y.-C., K. Rogoff and B. Rossi. 2008. Can Exchange Rates Forecast Commodity Prices? Working Paper. Harvard University. Cheng, K. C. 2008. Dollar Depreciation and Commodity Prices. In: IMF (ed.). 2008. World Economic Outlook. International Monetary Fund. Washington D.C. 72–75. Clements, K. W. and R. Fry. 2006. Commodity Currencies and Currency Commodities. CAMA Working Paper. Cremer, J. and D. Isfahani. 1991. Models of the Oil Market. Harwood Academic Publishers. New York. Crespo Cuaresma, J., A. Jumah and S. Karbuz. 2007. Modelling and Forecasting Oil Prices: The Role of Asymmetric Cycles. Working Paper. Faculty of Economics and Statistics. University of Innsbruck. Forthcoming in: The Energy Journal 2009. Diebold, F. X. and R. S. Mariano. 1995. Comparing Predictive Accuracy. In: Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 13. 253–263. ECB. 2007. Oil-exporting Countries: Key Structural Features, Economic Developments and Oil Revenue Recycling. Monthly Bulletin. July. 75–86. European Commission. 2006. Quarterly Report on the Euro Area. Directorate General for Economic and Financial Affairs. Brussels. Frankel, J. A. 2006. Commodity Prices, Monetary Policy, and Currency Regimes. NBER Working Paper. Frenkel, J. A. 1976. A Monetary Approach to the Exchange Rate: Doctrinal Aspects and Empirical Evidence. In: The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 78. 200–224. Habib, M. M. and M. M. Kalamova. 2007. Are there Oil Currencies? The Real Exchange Rate of Oil Exporting Countries. Working Paper. European Central Bank. IMF. 2006. World Economic Outlook 01 – Globalization and Inflation. International Monetary Fund. Washington D.C. ITF. 2008. Interim Report on Crude Oil. Internagency Task Force on Commodity Markets. Washington D.C. MONETARY POLICY & THE ECONOMY Q4/08 119
You can also read