Concurrences - Sousa Ferro e Associados
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
Concurrences Revue des dRoits de la concuRRence | Competition Law JournaL “ Ceci n’est pas un marché ” : Gratuity and competition law Doctrines l Concurrences N° 1-2015 www.concurrences.com Miguel Sousa Ferro miguelferro@fd.ul.pt Guest Professor, University of Lisbon Law School, Lisbon
Doctrines “Ceci n’est pas AbstrACt constitutes a violation of the publisher's rights and may be punished by up to 3 years imprisonment and up to a € 300 000 fine (Art. L. 335-2 Code de la Propriété Intellectuelle). Personal use of this document is authorised within the limits of Art. L 122-5 Code de la Propriété Intellectuelle and DRM protection. Une analyse globale de la pratique judiciaire et Ce document est protégé au titre du droit d'auteur par les conventions internationales en vigueur et le Code de la propriété intellectuelle du 1er juillet 1992. Toute utilisation non autorisée constitue une contrefaçon, délit pénalement sanctionné jusqu'à 3 ans d'emprisonnement et 300 000 € d'amende (art. L. 335-2 CPI). L’utilisation personnelle est strictement autorisée dans les limites de l’article L. 122 5 CPI et des mesures techniques de protection pouvant accompagner ce document. This document is protected by copyright laws and international copyright treaties. Non-authorised use of this document administrative, centrée surtout sur les ordres juridiques européens, dans un grand nombre un marché” : de secteurs, montre qu’il y a des positions très divergentes sur le traitement de la gratuité au sein du droit de la concurrence. Cet article suggère que le droit de la concurrence ne s’applique pas à des Gratuity and exchanges véritablement gratuites (de gratis non curat lex), mais des produits gratuits peuvent être pris en compte dans l’application du droit de la concurrence à des produits payés (e.g. pour la détermination du pouvoir competition law de marché). Il est aussi suggéré que le droit européen de la concurrence ne permet pas la définition de marchés gratuits, et qu’il est très improbable que des produits/services gratuits puissent être inclus dans des marchés de produits/services payés. An overall analysis of judicial and administrative practice, focused Miguel Sousa Ferro* predominantly on EU legal orders, relating to miguelferro@fd.ul.pt a wide range of sectors, shows highly Guest Professor, University of Lisbon Law School, Lisbon divergent and contradictory positions concerning the treatment of gratuity under competition law. This paper argues that competition law does not apply to truly gratuitous exchanges (de gratis non curat lex), but free products may be taken into account in the enforcement of competition law to paid products (e.g. when assessing market I. Introduction power). It is also argued that European competition law does not allow for the definition of gratuitous markets, and it is highly unlikely that free products/services can be included in markets with paid products/ 1. The offer of products and services free of charge precedes competition law. services. Be it with commercial intent, or to fulfill a public mission, or with an altruistic or charitable goal, a myriad of economically useful goods have been and continue to be offered in a variety of circumstances. * This is an abbreviated and revised version of the working paper M. Sousa Ferro, “Ceci n’est pas 2. European competition authorities and courts have, since long, had to tackle un marché”: Gratuity and competition law, 2014, available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=2493236, the possibility of enforcing competition law in the context of free products/ which includes further details on the underlying services. However, nowhere can we find a unified position on the treatment of research. The author thanks Professors João Gata, John Newman, Laurence Idot, Michal Gal, gratuity under competition law. No authority has yet approached this issue in a Rolf Weber and Spencer Weber Waller for their global manner. Piecemeal approaches have led to contradictory results. Solutions helpful comments to that earlier draft of this paper. have varied between authorities and, within the practice of the same authority, The opinions presented herein are the author’s alone, as is the responsibility for any errors. between economic sectors and even between cases in the same sector. And yet, this is a horizontal issue of principle, which must receive a homogenous reply. 3. Looking at the worldwide practice of market definition in the context of gratuitous products and services, Prof. Evans justly noted: “(…) there is a tendency on part of companies, authorities, and courts to do more hand waving than serious analysis when they encounter products and services offered for free.”1 4. Only recently has doctrine begun to discuss gratuity in antitrust comprehensively.2 Even those who have paid closer attention to this issue have approached it from a fundamentally economic perspective, most working on the assumption that competition law should and can apply to “free markets,” and 1 D. Evans, Antitrust Economics of Free, (2011) 7(1) CPI 71, at p. 73. 2 See, e.g.: D. Evans, cit.; F. Polverino, Hunting the Wild Geese: Competition Analysis in a World of “Free”, (2012) Concorrenza e mercato 545; J. D. Newman, Antitrust in Zero-Price Markets, July 2014, available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=2474874. Concurrences N° 1-2015 I Doctrines I Miguel Sousa Ferro I “Ceci n’est pas un marché” : Gratuity and competition law I 1
that gratuitous exchanges can be defined as a relevant 8. The fact that discussions tend to arise exclusively in constitutes a violation of the publisher's rights and may be punished by up to 3 years imprisonment and up to a € 300 000 fine (Art. L. 335-2 Code de la Propriété Intellectuelle). Personal use of this document is authorised within the limits of Art. L 122-5 Code de la Propriété Intellectuelle and DRM protection. market and as an economic activity under competition the context of multilateral markets or of free products Ce document est protégé au titre du droit d'auteur par les conventions internationales en vigueur et le Code de la propriété intellectuelle du 1er juillet 1992. Toute utilisation non autorisée constitue une contrefaçon, délit pénalement sanctionné jusqu'à 3 ans d'emprisonnement et 300 000 € d'amende (art. L. 335-2 CPI). L’utilisation personnelle est strictement autorisée dans les limites de l’article L. 122 5 CPI et des mesures techniques de protection pouvant accompagner ce document. This document is protected by copyright laws and international copyright treaties. Non-authorised use of this document law.3 with paid companion products has made it more difficult to discuss gratuity in itself, diverting attention to the 5. In recent years, this issue has started attracting greater need to take into account the effects of free products on attention, mostly thanks to the growing number of certain markets. gratuitous services whose supply has been made possible by the Internet and by software development, and a 9. This has obscured the fact that there may actually be number of high-profile cases dealing with multilateral no doctrinal disagreement on the basic issue that there is platforms or bundling with one gratuitous product. no such thing as a completely gratuitous relevant market, and that competition law has no role to play in the 6. After providing a general framework in which to regulation of entirely non-commercial exchanges. In this conduct this analysis, in a manner that duly distinguishes sense, there is probably a lot more to be learned from the different situations (II.), this paper will discuss cases that never arise than from those that actually do: whether competition law may be applied to gratuitous silence (lack of intervention) speaks louder than words. exchanges (III.) and whether there can be such a thing as a gratuitous market or a market including free products/ 10. There are two contextual variations of gratuity which services, and how free products can be taken into account are irrelevant for this discussion. in competitive assessments (IV.). While, section III logically precedes section IV, the two are interrelated, 11. First, the existence of a profit-making goal is not as the latter becomes unnecessary if competition law is legally relevant. EU competition law applies to any entity inapplicable, but the answer to section III also depends engaged in an economic activity, irrespective of its legal on the conclusions in section IV. status and the way in which it is financed (businesses, public authorities, charities…).4 II. General 12. Second, it may be argued that variations of gratuity/ non-gratuity in time must be taken into account. The case framework for may be that a product: (a) was previously paid; (b) will or is likely to be paid in the future; or (c) will (presumably) always be free. However, for the purposes of this analysis discussion, this dynamic dimension may be disregarded, and we should focus on scenarios of unchanged gratuity.5 7. Arguably, the greatest obstacle to the development of a unified theoretical position on the relationship 13. As for the variations which are relevant, the first is the between gratuity and competition law, in what concerns means of financing gratuity. its applicability and market definition, has been the lack of differentiation between fully gratuitous situations and 14. Economically, nothing can be supplied for free. situations of gratuitous supply with an impact on paid The costs of providing the goods or services in question products, as well as the distinction between different (even if limited to time expended in their creation and degrees of impact. maintenance) can be subsidized by non-commercial activities (charity, public funding, user-built platforms…), or by commercial activities. The source of subsidization is crucial because asking where the money comes from is the same as asking which activities are being benefited by 3 See, e.g.: P. J. Harbour and T. I. Koslov, Section 2 in a Web 2.0 World: the free offers and how. An Expanded Vision of Relevant Product Markets, (2010) 76 ALJ 769; R. I. McEwin and C. Chew, China—the Baidu Decision, (2010) 6(2) CPI 223; T. Vecchi, J. Vidal and V. Fallenius, The Microsoft/Yahoo! 15. There may be commercial subsidization which is Search Business Case, (2010-2) CPN 41; G. A. Manne and J. D. Wright, very remote and unclear, but nonetheless clearly present. Google and the Limits of Antitrust: The Case against the Case against Google, (2011) 34 HJLPP 171; A. H. Zhang, Using a Sledgehammer Supplying a free service/product may provide a company to Crack A Nut: Why China’s Anti-Monopoly Law was Inappropriate with competitive advantages thanks to brand recognition for Renren v. Baidu, (2011) 7(1) CPI; Polverino, cit.; S. Weber or good will. A company may provide a range of Waller, Antitrust and Social Networking, (2011-2012) 90 NCLR 1771; M. S. GAL, Viral Open Source: Competition vs. Synergy, (2012) 8(3) free products/services (through charitable endeavors, JCLE 469; H. A. Shelanski, Information, Innovation, and Competition scientific patronage, etc.), and yet it is expectable that Policy for the Internet, (2012) 161 UPLR 1663; A. Daly, Free Software and the Law: Out of the Frying Pan and into the fire: How Shaking Up the shareholders believe that, overall, the company has Intellectual Property Suits Competition Just Fine, (2013) 3 Journal of something to gain from this activity. Peer Production; F Thépot, Market Power in Online Search and Social- Networking: A Matter of Two-Sided Markets, (2013) 36(2) WC 195; R. H. Weber, Competition Law Issues in the Online World, (2013) 20th St.GICLF ICF, available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=2341978; N. Zingales, Product Market Definition in Online Search and Advertising, (2013) 9(1) CLR 29; C. J. Hoofnagle and J. Whittington, Free: Accounting for the Costs of the Internet’s Most Popular Price, 4 See, e.g.: Case C-437/09 etc., AG2R Prévoyance [2011] ECR I-973, (2014) 61 UCLALR 606. As notable exceptions to this state of affairs, § 40-41; and L. Idot, Entreprise sociale et concurrence, Concurrences see: J. D. Ratliff and D. L. Rubinfeld, Is there a Market for Organic no 1-2013. Search Engine Results and can their Manipulation Give Rise to Antitrust Liability?, (2014) 10(3) JCLE 1; and Newman, cit., at p. 21 et seq. 5 See Evans, cit., footnote 21; and Sousa Ferro, cit., at pp. 5-6. 2 I Concurrences N° 1-2015 I Doctrines I Miguel Sousa Ferro I “Ceci n’est pas un marché” : Gratuity and competition law
16. But, often, one can identify (based on economic reality (and despite some general affirmations by administrative constitutes a violation of the publisher's rights and may be punished by up to 3 years imprisonment and up to a € 300 000 fine (Art. L. 335-2 Code de la Propriété Intellectuelle). Personal use of this document is authorised within the limits of Art. L 122-5 Code de la Propriété Intellectuelle and DRM protection. and the expected rational behavior of economic agents) authorities excluding applicability). Only in recent cases, Ce document est protégé au titre du droit d'auteur par les conventions internationales en vigueur et le Code de la propriété intellectuelle du 1er juillet 1992. Toute utilisation non autorisée constitue une contrefaçon, délit pénalement sanctionné jusqu'à 3 ans d'emprisonnement et 300 000 € d'amende (art. L. 335-2 CPI). L’utilisation personnelle est strictement autorisée dans les limites de l’article L. 122 5 CPI et des mesures techniques de protection pouvant accompagner ce document. This document is protected by copyright laws and international copyright treaties. Non-authorised use of this document close relations of subsidization of free products by paid especially in the IT sector, have companies begun to ones. There may be: (a) cross-subsidies by companion clearly argue this point. products (e.g. buy 1, get 1 free; complementary products such as coffee machines and their capsules; etc.); 22. Microsoft did so before the EGC, but was unsuccessful (b) freemium offers (premium upgrade strategies); and because the Court considered that there was not really (c) multisided platforms (e.g. media/advertising). gratuity and because there was tying with a paid product (leveraging concerns).6 Baidu, a search engine, raised 17. The second relevant factor is interchangeability with it unsuccessfully before a Chinese court, which noted paid products/services. If there is not at least a small that the search function was tied to the supply of paid degree of actual or potential interchangeability, free (advertising) services.7 On the other hand, Google raised products become irrelevant in competitive assessments it successfully before an American federal court, which relating to paid products. found that there could be no antitrust relevant market for something given away for free (even though it allowed for 18. When pondering interchangeability, one should the possibility that the result might have been different if keep in mind specificities of different groups of users/ the applicant had relied on an approach that took into costumers. A free product may be interchangeable with a paid one for some consumers, but not for others who account the presence of a multilateral platform).8 may, for example, be incapable or unwilling to enter the market at any price. However, one should consider 23. Prof. Evans has argued that “there is no reason why a free product as “interchangeable” with a paid one, in these [gratuitous] goods should receive any antitrust this sense, if it is so for at least a significant group of exemption through, for example, concluding (…) that there consumers, which would justify supply on a commercial is no relevant antitrust market for a free good.”9 From a basis. legal perspective, while we agree with the sentiment (read in the context in which it was formulated), we cannot 19. In light of the foregoing, the enforcement of agree with such a broad phrasing. It is our belief that competition law in a specific situation involving gratuity there are, in fact, decisive legal reasons to conclude that should begin by framing it according to these two factors, competition law does not apply to (truly) gratuitous as described in the following table. exchanges. 24. In the UK, the definition of a “business” for the Means of subsidizing gratuity* purposes of applying competition law refers, inter alia, Interchan- geability Close Remote Non-commercial to “an undertaking in the course of which goods or services with paid commercial commercial subsidization products subsidization subsidization are supplied otherwise than free of charge.”10 The same (Type 3) (Type 2) must be true, we argue, in EU law and in the competition (Type 1) law of other EU Member States. Yes 1A 2A 3A (Type A) 25. One author has noted that new non-corporate free approach, “may still confound competition law or at least No 1B 2B 3B the tenets on which it is based,” as they challenge “the (Type B) 6 Case T-201/04, Microsoft v. Commission [2007] ECR II-3601, § 960 and III. Gratuity and 7 968-969; See Polverino, cit., section 2.3. Renren v. Baidu, Opinion by Beijing No. 1 Intermediate People’s Court, the applicability Civil Case no. 845/2009 (“[t]he free search service provided by search engine providers to internet users is not equivalent to a free service for charity, and may obtain actual or potential commercial benefits by attracting internet users and employing advertisement or other of competition law marketing services”). See: Evans, cit.; McEwin and Chew, cit.; Zhang, cit. 8 KinderStart.com v. Google, 2007 WL 831806 (N. D. Cal.). As quoted 21. It is remarkable that competition law has so often been in Evans, cit., the federal court stated: “KinderStart cites no authority applied to free products/services without any significant indicating that antitrust law concerns itself with competition in the discussion of its applicability to gratuitous exchanges provision of free services. (…) KinderStart has not alleged that anyone pays Google to search. Thus, the Search Market is not a “market” for purposes of antitrust law.” 9 Evans, cit. Even jurists who argue for the applicability of competition * Different means of subsidizing gratuity may coexist for any single law to free goods/services are forced to admit that it is difficult to free product/service. But, for the purposes of identifying competitive imagine a private enforcement case aimed at protecting consumers concerns, the presence of close commercial subsidization is more from anticompetitive practices associated to free products, since important than of remote commercial subsidization, and even more so current case law does not allow for a finding of damage to property in than of non-commercial subsidization. Therefore, for the purposes of such situations—see: Newman, cit., pp. 22-25, concluding that “such qualifying offers of free products/services within the types indicated in consumers would likely lack standing.” this table: if a given situation can simultaneously be qualified as type 1A and type 2A, we shall refer to it merely as type 1A, etc. 10 Enterprise Act 2002, Section 129(1). Concurrences N° 1-2015 I Doctrines I Miguel Sousa Ferro I “Ceci n’est pas un marché” : Gratuity and competition law I 3
very existence of capitalist production and markets.”11 dominant position, depending on the delineation of the constitutes a violation of the publisher's rights and may be punished by up to 3 years imprisonment and up to a € 300 000 fine (Art. L. 335-2 Code de la Propriété Intellectuelle). Personal use of this document is authorised within the limits of Art. L 122-5 Code de la Propriété Intellectuelle and DRM protection. But even scholars raising this sensitive point have argued relevant market and the number of charities engaged in the Ce document est protégé au titre du droit d'auteur par les conventions internationales en vigueur et le Code de la propriété intellectuelle du 1er juillet 1992. Toute utilisation non autorisée constitue une contrefaçon, délit pénalement sanctionné jusqu'à 3 ans d'emprisonnement et 300 000 € d'amende (art. L. 335-2 CPI). L’utilisation personnelle est strictement autorisée dans les limites de l’article L. 122 5 CPI et des mesures techniques de protection pouvant accompagner ce document. This document is protected by copyright laws and international copyright treaties. Non-authorised use of this document that competition law should apply to entirely gratuitous same activity (e.g. market for the supply of free meals in contexts, with no impact on the exchange of paid products. Brussels), since none of the exceptions to the existence of an economic activity, explicitly mentioned in the case law 26. As noted above, EU competition law applies to any of the Court, are applicable to such organizations. entity engaged in an economic activity, irrespective of its legal status and the way in which it is financed. According 31. One cannot argue that the demand for charitable to settled case law, an economic activity is “any activity supplies is not, and would not, be present on any market. consisting in offering goods or services on a given market.”12 The natural tendency to exclude such situations from the The concepts of economic activity and relevant market scope of competition law does not rest on an absolute lack have thus become inextricably linked: An offer of goods of (actual or potential) impact on commercial activities. or services can only be qualified as an economic activity if it happens in a market, and you cannot conceive of a It also cannot rest on the lack of a profit motive,14 nor, market without an economic activity. by itself, on the goal being pursued,15 as the Court has clearly stated that these are not relevant. They may be excluded on the basis of a de minimis approach,16 but that One cannot argue that the demand for requires defining relevant markets, assessing effects on charitable supplies is not, and would not, the market and starting from the assumption that such be present on any market charitable activities could be subject to competition law, if their impact were significant. 27. Thus, if one concludes (as will be argued in section IV.3.) that there is no such thing as a gratuitous 32. The key for the exclusion of such activities is, market in competition law, this may actually render I believe, the fully non-commercial origin of the funding competition law inapplicable to certain gratuitous offers of the free product or service. Such situations are of goods or services, to the extent that, in themselves, non-economic in nature. And there is no reason why they do not constitute an economic activity.13 this assessment should change if the non-commercially funded free product competes with paid products, i.e. in 28. But we can also arrive at the same result through a type 3A situations. different approach, which does not rely on the arguments regarding market definition. 33. If a Member State decides to gratuitously provide a 29. We have been unable to identify any example of service, and over 50% of the consumers of the preexisting enforcement of competition law to type 3B situations. (paid) services stop purchasing them and become users of It is instinctively clear that competition law does not the free service, does this mean that the State has become apply to these situations. Competition law aims to protect a competitor on the relevant market for this service and the competitive process, ultimately so as to increase can be found to be in abuse of its dominant position by consumer welfare. If a product/service is neither sold nor charging below cost prices? Is this not what frequently purchased, and if is not interchangeable with products happens in the socialized health sector (which can be dealt that are sold and purchased, nor does it have an effect on with, under the case law, in a different way)?17 Or does markets that subsidize its gratuity, there are no consumers it mean that a new autonomous gratuitous market was (only users or beneficiaries) and no competitive process formed, and that competition law can be used to force the to protect. State to extend the benefit of that free service to all those who believe their needs are sufficiently satisfied by it? 30. To argue otherwise implies accepting, for example, that Of course not. The activity is not commercially subsidized charitable NGOs supplying meals to the indigent would and is not economic in nature. Competition law has no be subject to competition law, and might indeed be in a right to prevent a State from pursuing its public goals by providing free products or services, nor can it interfere in the setting of criteria for the scope of beneficiaries. 11 Daly, cit. See also: Gal, cit. 12 See, e.g.: Case 118/85, Commission v. Italy [1987], ECR 2599, § 7; Case C-35/96, Commission v. Italy [1998] ECR I-3851, § 36; Case 34. Similarly, it is not the role of competition law to impose C-180/98 etc., Pavlov [2000] ECR I-6451, § 75; Case T-155/04, restrictions on the supply of free goods and services by SELEX v. Commission [2006] ECR II-4797, § 50 and 61-62; Case NGOs who sell nothing on any market, even if those C-1/12, OTOC [2013] (not yet reported), § 36. Only in exceptional circumstances, of facilitation of anticompetitive agreements by others, has the Court allowed for the application of art. 101 TFEU (never 102) to “undertakings which do not compete on any product market”—see: Case T-99/04, AC-Treuhand v. Commission [2008] II-1501, § 122 and 14 See: Case C-49/07, MOTOE [2008] ECR I-4863, § 23 et seq.; Case 127; Case T-379/10 etc., Keramag et al v. Commission [2013] (not C-1/12, cit., § 57. yet reported), § 91. Even in these cases, the undertakings in question 15 See: Case C-309/99, cit., § 58; Case C-437/09, § 45 (“the social aim of were active on some service markets and had a turnover generated by an insurance scheme is not in itself sufficient to preclude the activity in commercial sales, just not on the markets affected by the anticompetitive question from being classified as an economic activity”). practices. 16 See, by analogy: Case C-180/98 etc., cit., § 97. 13 Additionally, the scope of a market may affect whether a practice is considered de minimis, also affecting the applicability of prohibitions. 17 See Case T-319/99, FENIN [2003] ECR II-357, § 39-44. 4 I Concurrences N° 1-2015 I Doctrines I Miguel Sousa Ferro I “Ceci n’est pas un marché” : Gratuity and competition law
goods or services are interchangeable with paid ones.18 39. In such cases, the effects of gratuitous offers on constitutes a violation of the publisher's rights and may be punished by up to 3 years imprisonment and up to a € 300 000 fine (Art. L. 335-2 Code de la Propriété Intellectuelle). Personal use of this document is authorised within the limits of Art. L 122-5 Code de la Propriété Intellectuelle and DRM protection. Nor should it be used to stifle the altruistic donation of paid products may raise competitive concerns. But the Ce document est protégé au titre du droit d'auteur par les conventions internationales en vigueur et le Code de la propriété intellectuelle du 1er juillet 1992. Toute utilisation non autorisée constitue une contrefaçon, délit pénalement sanctionné jusqu'à 3 ans d'emprisonnement et 300 000 € d'amende (art. L. 335-2 CPI). L’utilisation personnelle est strictement autorisée dans les limites de l’article L. 122 5 CPI et des mesures techniques de protection pouvant accompagner ce document. This document is protected by copyright laws and international copyright treaties. Non-authorised use of this document time and effort by users who jointly develop contents for a gratuitous offer, in itself, does not. If it were not for its web portal or software that is made freely available to all.19 impact on a paid market, we would be all too happy to see consumer welfare improved by donations from a 35. It is one thing to take into account the competitive company (we would be in a type 2 situation). pressure exercised by these free products/services when analyzing paid markets (without including them in the 40. Even in type 1 situations, the offer of a free product/ relevant market). It is something entirely different to hold service does not, by itself, constitute an economic that a law aimed at preventing distortions of competition activity. As a rule, that product is not a good being and increasing consumer welfare can be used to impose offered on a “market,” as defined in competition law restrictions on public or private entirely non-commercial (see section IV.3.). initiatives. 41. There are goods (paid ones) being offered on markets 36. We have also not found any example of purely type 2 that are affected by those free offers. But the economic situations being the target of competition law enforcement nature of one activity cannot generally be extended, by by European authorities. The reason, we believe, is that we contagion, to another. The criterion for what constitutes also instinctively exclude the relevance of a link between an economic activity, as clarified in the case law, is a the offer of a free product and commercial interests functional one: in “competition law, the term ‘undertaking’ associated to the offer of paid products, if that link is must be understood as designating an economic unit for the remote. In such cases, there is commercial subsidization, purpose of the subject matter of the agreement [practice] but the link with paid products is not significant enough in question.”20 Thus, in principle, classification “as an to raise competitive concerns. It is certainly possible economic activity must be carried out separately for each for a company’s competitive success on (paid) markets activity exercised by a given entity.”21 to be affected by patronage activities. But in order for competition law to be concerned with those effects, they 42. This raises the crucial issue of whether competition would have to be significant enough and, if so, there law may legitimately be used to impose restrictions on a would probably be a close relation of subsidization by a non-economic (free) activity because of its impact on an paid product (i.e., a type 1 situation). economic (paid) activity. The answer to this question may be provided by two ideas. 37. Additionally, in these situations, we believe the altruistic nature of the activity and its positive social The need to ensure the effet utile (and welfare) impact still outweigh any concerns raised by potential and rather indeterminate positive effects of competition law on commercial interests. To believe otherwise would 44. First, the need to ensure the effet utile of competition mean that any form of patronage by businesses would law. There may be cases where, if obligations are not be included in a relevant market and be fully subject to imposed on the free product with an impact on a paid competition law. one, the goals of competition law cannot be achieved 38. Differently, in type 1A and type 1B situations, the in relation to the latter. In such cases, there is a need to gratuitous supply of a free product or service may have a intervene in a type 1 free product to achieve the law’s goal, (at least potential) significant impact on the remunerated and the restriction of the non-economic activity may be commercial activity that subsidizes it. Success on the justified by a judgment of proportionality, given that this free side of a multilateral platform funded by advertising activity is, in fact, closely associated to the promotion of affects success on the advertising market. The fact that an economic activity. potential customers are accustomed to the free version of a software program may make it easier to sell them the Exceptions to the functional approach upgraded paid version of it. Offering a product for free may to the concept of economic activity give a company an advantage when competing in a market for products used in combination with it. And so on. 45. Second, this may be seen as one of the exceptions to the above quoted functional approach to the concept of economic activity. Indeed, the Court has noted that the non-economic nature of an activity carried out by public authorities renders also non-economic the associated 18 Imagine that an NGO fighting for privacy decides to promote its goals by activity of purchase of necessary inputs, which would distributing free antivirus and anti-spyware software. This NGO has no commercial activity whatsoever. Is this activity subject to competition otherwise have an economic nature.22 In these cases, law? Its program can become quite successful and drastically reduce the the conduct on the (upstream) market occurs with no volume of the market for such software. But that does not change the fact that its activity is inherently uncommercial. Ceteris paribus, could it ever be found guilty of an infringement of competition law? Even if it were, such a finding could never lead to fines, as the maximum limit of 20 Case 170/83, Hydrotherm [1984], ECR 271, § 11. 10% of sales in the preceding year would, in this case, be zero. 21 Case C-49/07, cit., § 25. See also: Case T-155/04, cit., § 54-55, 87 and 19 For an example of such situations that demonstrates the specificities 92; Case 118/85, cit. § 7; and Idot, cit., §29-31. of an American antitrust approach, see: US 7th Circ. Court Appeals, Wallace v. IBM (06-2454). 22 Case T-319/99, cit., § 37. See also Case T-155/04, cit., § 61. Concurrences N° 1-2015 I Doctrines I Miguel Sousa Ferro I “Ceci n’est pas un marché” : Gratuity and competition law I 5
commercial intent or application. By analogy, it may – it refused to apply competition law to free constitutes a violation of the publisher's rights and may be punished by up to 3 years imprisonment and up to a € 300 000 fine (Art. L. 335-2 Code de la Propriété Intellectuelle). Personal use of this document is authorised within the limits of Art. L 122-5 Code de la Propriété Intellectuelle and DRM protection. be argued that the economic nature of a paid activity public health services, while not excluding Ce document est protégé au titre du droit d'auteur par les conventions internationales en vigueur et le Code de la propriété intellectuelle du 1er juillet 1992. Toute utilisation non autorisée constitue une contrefaçon, délit pénalement sanctionné jusqu'à 3 ans d'emprisonnement et 300 000 € d'amende (art. L. 335-2 CPI). L’utilisation personnelle est strictement autorisée dans les limites de l’article L. 122 5 CPI et des mesures techniques de protection pouvant accompagner ce document. This document is protected by copyright laws and international copyright treaties. Non-authorised use of this document may extend to an associated (free) activity, which would its possible applicability to paid health care otherwise not be economic, since the gratuitous activity provided by public hospitals;29 is being carried out to achieve (or at least has the result – it confirmed that the conditions imposed of achieving) an advantage in competition on the market on the free supply of freezers could violate (it occurs with a commercial intent and/or application). competition law, because of their impact on Some support for this approach may also be found in the market for impulse ice cream;30 the OTOC case, which demonstrated that an activity which in itself is not economic, such as the setting of – it rejected Germany’s argument that the Bundesanstalt rules by a chartered accountants association, may violate “cannot be classified as an undertaking within the competition law (it becomes economic) because of its meaning of article [102] of the Treaty, in so far as association to and impact on markets for paid services.23 the employment procurement services are provided free of charge,” in a context where the beneficiaries 46. As further support for these conclusions, we point financed the office’s activities through mandatory out that the ECJ has, on several occasions, justified the contributions (regardless of whether they used identification of an economic activity on the basis that the the services) and where these activities were services in question were offered “for payment” (or “for provided in actual (if not legal) competition remuneration”), sometimes adding that the entities with paid services by private companies.31 carrying out these activities had assumed the respective financial risks.24 Competition law is not applicable to type 2 47. More importantly, the Court has applied competition or type 3 situations of gratuity, but it can be law to free products only in the presence of actual or applicable to type 1 situations potential effects over paid products, precisely in type 1 situations. Thus, for example: 48. In short, we believe that competition law is not applicable to type 2 or type 3 situations of gratuity, but – it accepted that competition law applies to that it can be applicable to type 1 situations, and even all of Skype’s activities in the market for lead to the imposition of obligations upon free products, “consumer communications services,” where a whenever this is necessary to protect competition on the minority of these services are paid;25 markets for the associated paid products which subsidize the gratuity of the products in question.32 – it seemed to consider that all offers on the “operating system market” and “work group 49. However, this does not mean that a competition server operating system market” were an authority may legitimately impose measures aimed at economic activity, even though some were free;26 increasing or preventing a reduction of output or quality – it rejected Microsoft’s argument that of the free product, or take such effects into account in article 102 TFEU could not apply to Windows merger assessment,33 if those effects or measures are not Media Player because it was provided for free. related to anticompetitive effects over a paid product. This was justified, not only with the idea that the price was hidden in the bundle’s price, but also that the practice in question affected paid products (the tied product and the paid media players);27 IV. Gratuity and – it qualified Eurocontrol’s assistance to market definition national administrations as an economic activity, on the basis that it was not actually 50. Now that we have clarified the conditions under free (its price was included in the States’ which competition law may (and may not) be applied financing of its overall expenditures) and that to free products/services, it is necessary to turn to the it could potentially be provided by private companies (for payment);28 29 Case T-319/99, cit., § 39 et seq. 30 Case T-65/98, Van den Bergh Foods [2003] ECR II-4653; Case C-552/03 P, Unilever Bestfoods [2006] ECR I-9091. 23 Case C-1/12, cit., § 41 et seq. 31 See: Case C-41/90, Höfner [1991] ECR I-1979, § 19-23; Case T-155/04, 24 See, e.g.: Case C-35/96, cit., § 37; Case C-180/98 etc., cit., § 76; Case cit., § 90; Case C-55/96, Job Centre [1997] ECR I- 7119, § 24-25. For C-475/99, Ambulanz Glöckner [2001] ECR I-8089, § 20; Case C-1/12, an analysis, from this perspective, of the case law relating to social cit., § 37. protection schemes, see Sousa Ferro, cit., pp. 14-15. 25 Case T-79/12, Cisco and Messagenet v. Commission [2013] (not yet 32 Therefore, we do not agree with the finding that a “tying arrangement reported). cannot exist when the tying product is not sold to the consumer, but is 26 Case T-167/08, Microsoft v. Commission [2012] (not yet reported). provided free of charge”—Stephen Jay Photography, Ltd. v. Olan Mills, Inc., 713 F. Supp. 937 (E.D. Va. 1989); and 903 F.2nd 988 (4th Cir. 27 Case T-201/04, cit., § 960 and 968-969. 1990). 28 Case T-155/04, cit., § 83-90. 33 As the EC has done, e.g., in M.5727, § 119. 6 I Concurrences N° 1-2015 I Doctrines I Miguel Sousa Ferro I “Ceci n’est pas un marché” : Gratuity and competition law
crucial issue of how to define markets in the presence of but a very high share in the readers market (if the free constitutes a violation of the publisher's rights and may be punished by up to 3 years imprisonment and up to a € 300 000 fine (Art. L. 335-2 Code de la Propriété Intellectuelle). Personal use of this document is authorised within the limits of Art. L 122-5 Code de la Propriété Intellectuelle and DRM protection. such products or services. We will begin by looking at the newspaper is included therein). A software company that Ce document est protégé au titre du droit d'auteur par les conventions internationales en vigueur et le Code de la propriété intellectuelle du 1er juillet 1992. Toute utilisation non autorisée constitue une contrefaçon, délit pénalement sanctionné jusqu'à 3 ans d'emprisonnement et 300 000 € d'amende (art. L. 335-2 CPI). L’utilisation personnelle est strictement autorisée dans les limites de l’article L. 122 5 CPI et des mesures techniques de protection pouvant accompagner ce document. This document is protected by copyright laws and international copyright treaties. Non-authorised use of this document far-reaching impact of this discussion in practice. We will believed it held only a small fraction of the market may then provide a general overview of EU and Member suddenly be faced with a presumption of dominance (and State law and practice in this regard. Finally, we will a reversal of the burden of proof) if the competing free present our conclusions and discuss how free products software is excluded from the market. The Commission can be taken into account in competitive assessments may believe it has the right to inspect the premises of a beyond the step of market definition. company that is only present on the targeted market with a free good, but the courts might disagree. 51. At the outset, it should be noted that we are unaware of any examples in other branches of European law where 55. Because of the need to ensure the uniform enforcement of the term “market” is used to describe an ensemble of EU competition law and of the practical importance of market non-synallagmatic exchanges. However, the enforcement definition precedents, it is not enough to take a case-by-case of European and national competition law has frequently approach. A general theoretical position needs to be adopted led to the definition of “free relevant markets,” or to the and, ideally, included in guidelines. This is the only way of inclusion of free products in relevant markets that also avoiding the multitude of contradictions identified below. included paid products. 2. EU and Member State law 1. Practical relevance and practice 52. For the purposes of assessing market power, it 56. EU law, soft law and case law has not yet explicitly does not matter whether one includes the competitive and decisively clarified whether it is acceptable to identify constraints posed by gratuitous products/services at a free relevant market, or to include free products/services the stage of market definition, or at a later stage, where in relevant markets. extra-market constraints (such as potential competition) are taken into account. Perhaps because of this, 57. ECN practice is contradictory and incoherent34. specialized doctrine has, until recently, tended to focus European competition authorities’ conclusions have on how to appropriately take into account free products been contradictory: (i) from one authority to the other; in competitive analysis, without paying much or any (ii) from one type of products/services to others; and even attention to market definition. (iii) within the practice of the same authority relating to the same products/services. Such a state of affairs is 53. However, it is neither superfluous nor academic to hardly reconcilable with the rule of law. discuss whether, as a matter of law, gratuitous markets exist, or whether gratuitous products/services should be included in relevant markets. The position one takes will 2.1 TV often have decisive legal consequences: 58. For TV (type 1A), no clear position can be found in the case law of the Court. The position of the European – it may have an impact on the applicability of Commission (EC) seems to be that there is no such thing competition law (III.); as viewer markets for free-to-air or free access TV (FTA). – although a market share does not Even though it has never had to decisively tackle this automatically lead to the identification of issue, and although the manner in which these markets market power, it is often the case that market have been addressed has left much to be desired,35 it shares have specific legal consequences, which has never accepted the frequent arguments in favor of may therefore vary depending on whether one including pay-TV and FTA in the same market, and has defines gratuitous markets or whether one never given any indication that it was inclined to define includes gratuitous products or services in the an FTA viewers market. relevant market. Such may be the case with a presumption of dominance, an obligation 59. Indeed, whenever confronted with mergers relating to notify concentrations (in some Member exclusively to FTA, the Commission does not even States), de minimis thresholds, benefit of block exemptions, etc.; 34 For a more detailed analysis of this practice, see Sousa Ferro, cit., at pp. 18-26. – it may affect the granting of individual 35 Since these are two-sided markets, a rigorous market definition should exemptions to anticompetitive agreements; distinguish between: (i) a viewers’ market for pay-TV (possibly further segmented); and (ii) a TV advertising market (possibly broader or – it may affect the scope of supervisory and narrower). Many of the EC’s decisions in this area have, unfortunately, investigative powers of the competition tended to be misleading, by simplifying and referring broadly to a authorities; etc. “television broadcast market,” or, simultaneously, to a “market for free access TV” and to a “market for pay-TV.” In doing so, the Commission is, firstly, including two different markets in one. Pay-TV must be assessed 54. A company that publishes a free newspaper may not on the basis of its impact on a viewers’ market and on an advertising market. Secondly, it may lead, and has indeed led, to the erroneous belief know whether it is obliged to notify a merger to an NCA, that a relevant market has been defined where the demand is made up of because it has a very low market share in advertising, viewers of FTA. Concurrences N° 1-2015 I Doctrines I Miguel Sousa Ferro I “Ceci n’est pas un marché” : Gratuity and competition law I 7
discuss a viewers’ market, simply stating: “(…) the les éditeurs pour pouvoir distribuer leurs chaînes.’”44 “(…) the constitutes a violation of the publisher's rights and may be punished by up to 3 years imprisonment and up to a € 300 000 fine (Art. L. 335-2 Code de la Propriété Intellectuelle). Personal use of this document is authorised within the limits of Art. L 122-5 Code de la Propriété Intellectuelle and DRM protection. relevant product market to be defined is the market for PCA considers that, in principle, one should not define an Ce document est protégé au titre du droit d'auteur par les conventions internationales en vigueur et le Code de la propriété intellectuelle du 1er juillet 1992. Toute utilisation non autorisée constitue une contrefaçon, délit pénalement sanctionné jusqu'à 3 ans d'emprisonnement et 300 000 € d'amende (art. L. 335-2 CPI). L’utilisation personnelle est strictement autorisée dans les limites de l’article L. 122 5 CPI et des mesures techniques de protection pouvant accompagner ce document. This document is protected by copyright laws and international copyright treaties. Non-authorised use of this document advertising in television broadcasting.”36 It has repeatedly autonomous viewers’ market, given that, in what concerns free stressed that “in the case of free-to-air TV there is a access TV, there is no direct commercial relation between commercial relationship only between the program supplier TV operators and their viewers, but only between the first and the advertising industry.”37 It envisages the “FTA and advertisers. In this sense, it is unlikely for the so-called TV market” as one where “broadcasters compete for viewers’ market to be a market in the strict economic sense advertising revenues,”38 and it measured market shares of the term, since FTA TV operators only compete for a in function of advertising revenue. The fact that it has larger audience share given the strict relation between this also used audience to measure market power is explained indicator and access to advertising income.”45 by the fact that this is a decisive criterion for attracting advertisers.39 2.2 Radio 60. However, this line of cases also shows that the EC 63. For radio (type 1B), the EC’s position has evolved has not taken a definitive position on the underlying significantly. In a first case, where these markets were not theoretical issue, as shown by the fact that, after defining the focus of the analysis, it referred in passage to “the an advertising market, the Commission added: “(…) it markets for radio broadcasting and radio advertising.”46 can be left open if there is, in the strict economic sense of Shortly thereafter, it identified “a relevant market for radio this notion, a market for viewers where the TV broadcasters advertising,” adding that, in the specific case, it was “not compete against each other for audience shares.”40 necessary to decide whether there is a relevant market for radio broadcasting.”47 More recently, it has seemed to settle on 61. Member State NCAs, while all trying to follow EU the idea that radio markets are limited to advertising, and Commission practice, have taken radically different do not include a (free) broadcasting market.48 stands, with no clearly predominant position emerging. Some countries (e.g., Germany and Italy) have rejected 64. The position of the Member States is equally the existence of FTA TV broadcasting markets, even if varied. There are both definitions of free markets (radio not discussing the issue in the clearest of terms. Others broadcasting markets) alongside advertising markets49 seem to have defined free markets or markets including and definitions limited to advertising markets, which free services, either by identifying FTA TV broadcasting (at least implicitly) reject the existence of a broadcasting markets alongside TV advertising markets (Ireland and market.50 Although rare, one finds statements such as Romania), or by including FTA TV and pay-TV in a the following: “(…) the radio broadcasting market is not single TV broadcasting market (Bulgaria and Poland). a services market in itself, since the consumer does not pay for the supply of the service, there being no economic 62. Some NCAs have changed position from case to case, relation between the listener and the radio broadcaster.”51 even during overlapping periods. Such is the case, for example, of Spain41 and the United Kingdom.42 Within these, there are those who reproduce the Commission’s position on this issue, treating the FTA TV market as being 2.3 Print media limited to advertising (France and Portugal), but incur 65. In the print media sector (type 1B), when looking at in the same problem of lack of clarity which eventually professional publications provided for free, and despite leads to a misinterpretation and a finding that the TV calling it a publishing market, the Commission actually viewers’ market is divided into an FTA TV market and delineated only a market for advertising and calculated a pay-TV market.43 This interpretation is then rectified in market shares accordingly.52 However two cases seemed subsequent decisions, leading even to general statements of to admit the existence of a readers market for free principle concerning the treatment of gratuity in the context press, by adhering to French precedents.53 In another of market definition: “L’Autorité de la concurrence a déjà case, where the notifying parties argued that the readers eu l’occasion de constater que ‘contrairement à l’édition de chaînes payantes, l’édition de chaînes gratuites n’est pas à proprement parler un marché dans la mesure où les distributeurs de bouquets de télévision ne rémunèrent pas 44 France: 12-DCC-101, § 15; 10-DCC-11, § 33. 45 Portugal: Ccent. 54/2006, § 20-21 (our translation). 46 M.553, § 17. 36 M.1889, § 12. 47 M.779, § 19. 37 M.2876, § 41. 48 M.5533, § 46-47. 38 M.2996, § 10-14. 49 Czech Republic: S732/2012; Portugal: Ccent. 17/2005; Romania: 201/02; 221/06. 39 See, e.g., M.810, § 9; and M.6547, § 35-38. 50 France: 07-A-09; Germany: B6-56-03; Portugal: Ccent. 54/2006; 40 M.779, § 15; M.1574, § 11; M.553, § 17 and 20. Ireland: M/13/033; Italy: C7046; Spain: N/07021; United Kingdom: ME/1550/02. 41 Compare SNC/0024/12 and N/07021 to C/0230/10 (§ 130). 51 Portugal: Ccent. 54/206, § 31 (our translation). 42 Compare CC Report of 2010/05/12; ME/4682/10 (§ 7-10); and ME/2811/06 (§ 123) (see also CA98/20/2002). 52 M.3197, § 24-27 and 50-51. 43 France: C2006/83, pp. 3-4; Portugal: Ccent. 1/2005, § 21-36. 53 M.665, § 9-10 and 14; M.3420, § 9 and 11. 8 I Concurrences N° 1-2015 I Doctrines I Miguel Sousa Ferro I “Ceci n’est pas un marché” : Gratuity and competition law
market included free newspapers, the Commission stated: 2.4 Internet constitutes a violation of the publisher's rights and may be punished by up to 3 years imprisonment and up to a € 300 000 fine (Art. L. 335-2 Code de la Propriété Intellectuelle). Personal use of this document is authorised within the limits of Art. L 122-5 Code de la Propriété Intellectuelle and DRM protection. “(…) although free newspapers influence the degree of Ce document est protégé au titre du droit d'auteur par les conventions internationales en vigueur et le Code de la propriété intellectuelle du 1er juillet 1992. Toute utilisation non autorisée constitue une contrefaçon, délit pénalement sanctionné jusqu'à 3 ans d'emprisonnement et 300 000 € d'amende (art. L. 335-2 CPI). L’utilisation personnelle est strictement autorisée dans les limites de l’article L. 122 5 CPI et des mesures techniques de protection pouvant accompagner ce document. This document is protected by copyright laws and international copyright treaties. Non-authorised use of this document penetration of paid for newspapers and can constitute a 70. It is certainly the case that competition authorities competitive constraint, paid for newspapers do not belong “have not yet established a clear policy on defining the to the same product market as free newspapers.”54 In markets for internet businesses”63 (types 1A and 1B). two more recent decisions, the Commission seemingly Initially, the EC left open the issue of whether the embraced—even if with no explicit discussion—the idea provision of free contents could be considered a market.64 that free newspapers should be included in a readers After that, market definition practice has split into two market.55 completely separate and irreconcilable branches. 66. Several NCAs seem to have firmly decided that there 71. In one group of cases relating to Internet contents is a market for readers of free newspapers (alongside and portals, the EC repeatedly defined markets for the the advertising market).56 These positions were taken “provision of paid for content” and for the “provision of without a single discussion of the problem of gratuity, Internet advertising space.”65 Even though the impact and they are affirmed even in decisions that implicitly of gratuity on market definition was not discussed as reject the existence of gratuitous markets in other sectors such, one finds statements such as: the “parties, as well (such as TV and radio broadcasting).57 as the joint venture are providing free Internet content, and are therefore on the Internet advertising market.”66 67. But there are also national decisions that specifically The Commission refused to identify a market for “gateway addressed free press and (at least implicitly) rejected its services,” mostly based on the fact that these services were inclusion in a readers market.58 And several NCAs have supplied free of charge and that their impact could be taken adopted positions that have changed from case to case.59 into account in the examination of other markets.67 68. In the UK, the tendency seems to be to refer 72. In another group of cases, the Commission has defined broadly to press markets, but to focus exclusively on the Internet content and services markets which included paid advertising side (without ignoring the two-sided nature and free services. All the while, it continued to identify a of the market). In one such case, the OFT stated: “As the separate market for Internet advertising, and has presented OFT’s competitive analysis is restricted to the consideration such delineations even when the portal in question was of free newspapers, the following assessment is focused exclusively financed by advertising.68 It accepted a possible on advertisers and readership impact is not considered market for “Internet search,” alongside a market for “search further.”60 But, without any justification for the slightly advertising and other forms of online advertising”—a situation different approach, there was also at least one case where described as “two-sided platforms serving both search users the OFT included an essentially free newspaper in the (for ‘free’) and advertisers (for remuneration).”69 readers market.61 73. We find a very similar split in NCAs’ market definition 69. In Portugal, most decisions have not included free practice: avoiding taking a stand;70 identifying only press in the readers market. However, recently, in a Internet advertising markets;71 identifying markets for merger involving free newspapers, where the contours Internet contents which seemingly include demand for free of the readers market could be decisive, the PCA contents;72 identifying Internet markets that include free clarified that it believes there can be such a thing as a services;73 identifying free Internet search markets;74 etc. “free market.” The notifying party argued that there could not be a market where products were given away for free. The NCA replied that it needed to define a readers market to take into account the impact on the 63 Weber, cit., at p. 1. advertising market, adding that gratuity was irrelevant: 64 M.973, § 8. “(…) it only matters that, in this market, publications compete by adopting different strategies to obtain readers 65 See, e.g., M.5676 and M.5779. and different forms of financing.”62 66 JV.5, § 26 67 JV.1, § 14. 68 See, e.g., M.2222 and M.2463. 54 M.3817, § 12-15 and 19-20. 69 M.5727, § 47, 85-87 and 112-119. A similar approach can be seen in the LiveUniverse v. Myspace case (CV 06-6994 AHM, 2007 WL 6865852 55 M.5273, § 13-16 and 24; M.5932, § 203 and 215. (C.D. Cal. Jun. 4, 2007)). A number of authors seem to agree with the 56 France: 09-DCC-72; Netherlands: 6689, §15; Romania: 221/2006. identification of (free) Internet search markets—see, e.g.: Polverino, cit., section 2.1; Thépot, cit., at pp. 205 et seq.; Weber, cit., at pp. 9 and 57 See, e.g., France: 05-A-18; 07-A-09. 15. For a different view, see: Manne and Wright, cit., at pp. 19 et seq. Some authors have suggested defining “data markets,” where also no 58 Austria: Supreme Court Judgment in case 16Ok15/08; Poland: RWR remuneration would be exchanged (see, e.g., Harbour and Koslov, cit.). 7/2004. 70 France: 13-D-07; Spain: S/0346/11. 59 In Italy, compare C7839 and C6549 to I651. In Ireland, compare M/07/064 to M/09/013. 71 France: 10-D-30; Portugal: Ccent. 41/2008; Spain: N/07021. 60 UK: ME/2880/07, § 7. 72 Portugal: Ccent. 5/2013; UK: ME/5882-12. 61 UK: ME/3315/07. 73 UK: ME/5233/11. 62 Portugal: Ccent. 21/2011, § 47-49. 74 UK: ME/4912/11; France: Trib. Com. Paris, 31/01/2012. Concurrences N° 1-2015 I Doctrines I Miguel Sousa Ferro I “Ceci n’est pas un marché” : Gratuity and competition law I 9
You can also read