CALIFORNIA STATE UNIVERSITY, NORTHRIDGE - California ...

Page created by Phyllis Acosta
 
CONTINUE READING
CALIFORNIA STATE UNIVERSITY, NORTHRIDGE

       Worker Cooperative Creation and Growth: Obstacles and Opportunities

       A graduate project submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the

Degree of Master of Public Administration in Public Sector Management and Leadership

                                         By

                                   Rogelio Garcia

                                      December 2020
Copyright by Rogelio Garcia 2020

                ii
The graduate project of Rogelio Garcia is approved:

____________________________________                  __________________

Dr. Elizabeth Trebow, PhD                             Date

____________________________________                  __________________

Dr. Ariane David, PhD                                 Date

____________________________________                  __________________

Dr. Anaïs Valiquette L’Heureux, PhD, Chair            Date

                             California State University, Northridge

                                              iii
Table of Contents

Copyright Page                                           ii

Signature Page                                           iii

Abstract                                                 vi

Introduction                                             1

Background                                               3

Literature Review                                        5

       Defining Worker Cooperatives                      5

       The Current State of Worker Coops                 7

       Worker Coops in Foreign States                    9

       US States and Cities Developing Worker Coops      12

       Anchor Institutions                               12

       Cost Per Job Ratio                                13

       Public-Private Partnership                        13

       Barriers to Worker Coop Development               14

       Insufficient Data                                 14

       Negative Stigma                                   15

       Efficiency Concerns                               15

       Ease of Transporting or Replicating               15

       Corporate Competition                             16

       Little to no Supporting Public Policy             17

       Education                                         17

                                               iv
Unfamiliarity with the Worker Coop Business Model   18

      Conversions                                         18

      Financing                                           19

      Governing Boards and Management                     19

      Limitations                                         20

Literature Review Summary                                 21

Research Question and Aim                                 22

Research Design                                           23

      General Approach                                    23

      Methods                                             23

      Qualitative Data Collection                         23

      Quantitative Data Collection                        24

Discussion                                                26

      Limitations                                         26

      Ethical Considerations                              26

      Expected Benefits/Contribution                      26

Conclusion                                                28

References                                                29

Appendix A                                                33

Appendix B                                                34

                                           v
Abstract

               Worker Cooperative Creation and Growth: Obstacles and Opportunities

                                                By

                                           Rogelio Garcia

            Master of Public Administration in Public Sector Management and Leadership

   Worker cooperatives represent one example of an alternative choice of employment. The

worker cooperative framework can vary, but essentially are businesses that are owned and self-

managed by the workers. Many industrialized countries are experiencing growing inequality,

especially over the last few decades. Worker cooperatives are seen as an alternative business

model to help provide their workers with a higher standard of living. The latest financial crisis

has brought worker cooperatives to the forefront yet again as a viable alternative business model.

However, the number of cooperative jobs overall created, which translates into 10% of the

world’s employed population, remains relatively low. This proposal aims to determine the

obstacles worker cooperatives in different sectors face and how these determine the extent to

which these affect worker co-ops creation and expansion. An exploratory approach is the method

chosen to collect qualitative data for this project. Method sampling will implement surveys and

interviews which will be given to various worker coop management. The findings here can help

future and present worker cooperatives navigate and mitigate the obstacles that the participants

mentioned. Public policy makers can benefit from data collected here by learning what inhibits

worker cooperatives from competing on an even playing field with traditional firms. Data from

                                                 vi
this research could be used by policy makers to help promote worker cooperative friendly

legislation which will increase employment opportunities.

                                              vii
Introduction

        Worker cooperatives represent one example of an alternative choice of employment. One

reason for the increased interest in worker cooperatives is due to the long-term trend by major

American companies to move their plants abroad and or outsourcing jobs (Bretos, Errasti &

Marcuello, 2019). This has led to a significant decrease in the quantity and quality of jobs

available. Individuals are not able to acquire full-time jobs with benefits as was the case before.

This means that the standard of living in the US has steadily lowered and most likely will

continue a downward trend (Chowdhury, 2018). Worker cooperatives can provide quality

employment and raise the standard of living for their workers as compared to traditional

corporate businesses (Olsen, 2013).

       The second reason for an increased interest in worker cooperatives is connected to the

last financial crisis that began in 2007. Many individuals fortunate enough to have full-time jobs

with benefits found themselves unemployed and their homes in foreclosure during the financial

crisis as major US corporations began to downsize and call in their loans. The official

unemployment rate jumped to over 10% during the financial crisis. This economic crisis gained

the interest of policymakers and researchers who are concerned with finding possible ways to

restructure economic organizations (Arando, Gago, Jones & Kato, 2019). The fragility of the

current economic system was exposed in 2007/2008, and many individuals still see it as a

potential threat to their livelihoods. Worker cooperatives can compete with market pressures and

better withstand financial crises while at the same time having a positive ripple effect in the local

economy (Baskaran, 2015). What are the key factors that influence worker cooperative

development? The answer to this question is important because worker cooperatives are designed

to create quality employment and to help in putting an end to cyclical unemployment (Landin,

                                                  1
2018). Ending cyclical unemployment is especially relevant today as the worldwide quarantine

in response to the Covid-19 pandemic has dramatically increased unemployment. Many

employers will undoubtedly not be able to fully recover from the shutting down of their business

and will not be able to rehire their employees. Finding answers to this question will ultimately

help in developing knowledge on how to remove obstacles for worker cooperatives creation and

make data available for policy makers who could create legislation that favors worker

cooperative development. The following chapters will give a little background and define worker

cooperatives. Worker cooperatives from around the globe will be analyzed to see how the

business model performs.

                                                 2
Background

  During the Great Depression thousands of worker cooperatives, also known as worker coops,

emerged to create new jobs for the mass of unemployed. Historically, worker coops proliferate

and gain popularity in times of economic distress or political upheaval (Baskaran, 2015). During

the 1960s and 1970s worker coops experienced a resurgence due in large part to the social justice

and political movements. In this context, worker coops were a way to give power to the people to

counter establishment values that were seen to negatively impact people and the community

(Camou, 2016). The financial crisis of 2007/2008 has brought worker coops to the forefront yet

again as a viable alternative business model. All 50 states have recognized and formalized

cooperatives into their laws but currently, only 12 states have specific laws for worker

cooperatives (Jacob, 2016).

       Public policy in California regarding worker coops is leading the way for the other 38

states that lack a specific and substantial worker coop policy (Jacob, 2016). The California

Worker Cooperative Act (AB 816) was signed by Governor Jerry Brown and came into effect on

January 1, 2016 (Blum, 2017). AB 816 amended existing cooperative law to provide both a legal

framework and the pathway for worker cooperatives to raise capital from their community.

Worker coops represent an alternative way of helping communities with existing unemployment.

Worker coops also represent a way to help communities withstand further economic downturns.

There is ample evidence that suggests traditional firms have less employment stability than

worker coops when confronted with demand shocks (Burdin, 2014). This means that worker

coops are less likely to fire employees and more likely to retain their employees when local or

global economies decline. These reasons alone warrant further studies into the impact and

outcomes of worker coops.

                                                 3
A renewed willingness to use the worker coop model throughout the world was apparent

after the 2008 economic collapse with the increase of grassroots economic initiatives to help

develop worker coops (Miller, 2010). Many industrialized countries are experiencing growing

inequality, especially over the last few decades. Growing global inequality makes for another

important reason to further study worker coop start-up factors and barriers. The number of

cooperative jobs created overall translates into 10% of the world’s employed population. This

number includes all types of cooperatives such as consumer, credit and worker cooperatives.

However, worker coops are present in almost all economic sectors and represent the most

common type of cooperative in the world (Guzman, Santos & Barroso, 2019). These grassroot

initiatives, if provided with adequate public policy support, could result in the formation of a

significant worker coop sector. However, caution needs to be taken because public policies can

increase the obstacles, deliberately or not, that worker coops face.

                                                 4
Literature Review

        This chapter focuses on the problems and barriers that worker coops face in their efforts

to start up as a business. In addition, barriers to the development of a worker coop business

sector are also analyzed and discussed. Worker coops from around the world will be compared

with firms that use the traditional business model to determine how they respond to similar

barriers to success. The worker coop model will be analyzed to see how it manages these

barriers.

Defining Worker Cooperatives

        Analyzing the key principles of worker coops will assist in understanding how they

function and what their goals are. Worker coop frameworks vary from each other, but essentially

they are businesses that are owned and self-managed by the workers. Member economic

participation is one principle that usually means that members contribute equitably and are in

control of the capital of their coop (Baskaran, 2015). This means workers/members are their own

boss and vote to allocate surpluses such as profits as they see fit. However, a portion of worker

coop profits, called indivisible reserves, are prohibited from being distributed to any worker.

These indivisible reserves are a restricted part of the worker coops capital structure and can only

be used for the firm’s ongoing capital needs (Jacob, 2016). A worker coop purchasing newer and

or more efficient technology would be a permitted use of indivisible reserves. The individual

reserve concept is important to a worker coops survival. This is because on average worker

coops are smaller than the competition which is mostly made up of traditional firms. Worker

coops try to ensure firm survival by requiring parts of the profits to be reinvested into the firm to

keep it as efficient and competitive as possible.

                                                    5
Sustainable development is another worker coop core principle. Sustainable development

here means a business that integrates well with the local community and improves the

community. Worker coops can help provide vulnerable workers with opportunities for stable and

safe employment (Baskaran, 2015). Rural communities around the world have increasingly

embraced worker coops because worker coops provide a way to create and preserve rural jobs

(Jacobs, 2019). The worker coop structure helps in avoiding layoffs during periods of economic

decline by making it easier to temporarily change worker salary level until the economy recovers

(Díaz-Foncea, & Marcuello, 2015). Employees all take a temporary pay cut to avoid or lessen the

number of workers that would have to be laid off during economic declines. This ability allows

for sustainable development which in turn helps to maintain and keep the local community

intact.

          Democratic member control is another worker coop principle. Workers actively

participate in high-level decisions about the direction of the company (Baskaran, 2015). There

are variations to the worker coop model but they mostly all have the same key principles. Each

worker gets one vote regardless of the share of capital they own. Workers vote and decide who

will be on their firms governing board and who the managers will be (Saleh & Hamzah, 2017).

Worker coop members also vote on who the members will be and how membership will be

granted and terminated.

          Coopetition is another worker coop key principle which is defined as simultaneous

cooperation and competition at multiple levels or even at an intra-organizational level

(Basterretxea, Charterina & Landeta, 2019). Coopetition is accomplished when two or more

worker coops mutually agree to provide each other with valuable assets such as capital,

knowledge, technology and managerial talent (Beamish & Lupton, 2015). Coopetition may

                                                 6
contain benefits and drawbacks. The main benefits of coopetition are oriented towards sharing

costs, increasing capacity, reaching economies of scale and reducing risks. The main drawbacks

of coopetition are knowledge leakage and opportunistic behavior (Baskaran, 2015). One study on

coopetition compared worker coops and traditional firms that were both engaged in the high

technology, knowledge-intensive and dynamic industries. The study found that coopetition

increased when market conditions were either extremely good or extremely bad (Basterretxea,

Charterina & Landeta, 2019). This means that worker coop creation and or expansion is more

difficult when market conditions are average. However, overall, there is little academic research

on how the worker coop principle of coopetition affects worker coop performance (Guzman &

Santos, 2019). More research needs to be done on the benefits and drawbacks that coopetition

has on worker coops.

The Current State of Worker Cooperatives

         Understanding the reasons why worker coops are more common in some cultures and

countries and not in others will provide clues about the obstacles and incentives associated with

their creation and expansion. Comparing worker coops with traditional capitalist firms can help

in obtaining data that can be used to explain why there are relatively fewer worker coops.

Despite being less numerous, worker coops are important to the world economy. According to

International Cooperative Alliance, which is a leading organization for all things coop, there are

3 million cooperatives in the world that are most active in insurance, agriculture, wholesale,

retail trade and banking (Kispál-Vitai, Regnard, Kovesi & Guillotte, 2019). The World

Cooperative Monitor analyzed the world's 300 largest cooperatives and found that they generate

a combined turnover of $2.5 trillion and created 280 million jobs (Guzman, Santos & Barroso,

2019).

                                                 7
The most common type of cooperative is an agricultural cooperative which represents

about 50% of all cooperatives (Grace, 2014). Banking and credit unions, which make up about

8% of all existing cooperatives, represent the next largest single category of cooperatives.

Worker cooperatives account for only about 3.5% of all cooperatives worldwide. (Grace, 2014).

Worker coops, although they represent a small percentage of cooperatives, are important and

different because they provide opportunities for workers to own the business they work in and

are operated democratically. Europe has about 31,500 worker coops with the majority of these

being located in Spain and Italy (Landin, 2018). The US has about 30,000 cooperatives with

about 27,000 of these categorized as consumer cooperatives (Artz & Kim, 2011). A little over

1% of these 30,000 cooperatives are categorized as worker coops which on average have 11 full-

time employees (Artz & Kim, 2011). Worker coops in the US, as of 2016, are only about 400

nationwide (Camou, 2016). When compared with the rest of the world, where worker coops

account for 3.5% of all cooperatives, the US has a much lower ratio of worker cooperatives at

1%. However, recent economic downturns have caused a renewed interest in worker coops.

       An increasing number of states and cities are contracting private companies to help

implement public policy (Miller, 2010). Public-private partnerships are situations where

governments contract private firms for the implementation of public policy (Wang, Xiong &

Zhu, 2017). This includes public services such as transportation, water and sewage, energy,

environment protection, public health and others. This current trend is a form of institutionalized

cooperation between cities and the private-sector. Worker coops are beginning to receive an

increasing amount of business from cities. These initiatives are more broadly known as the

solidarity economy (Miller, 2010). As mentioned before, people throughout the world have

                                                 8
increased grassroots economic initiatives after the 2008 financial crisis. This is an opportunity

that other countries are also using to develop a worker coop sector.

Worker Coops in Foreign States

       Most of Europe’s worker coops are found in Spain and Italy (Adeler, 2014). Spain and

Italy in particular have significant worker coop public policy as well as a developed worker coop

sector. However, public policy concerning coops, at least in these cases, came after the creation

of a robust worker coop sector (Diaz-Foncea & Marcuello, 2014). For example, the most

successful worker coop in the world is the Mondragon Corporation, is located in Spain’s

northern Basque region. Founded in 1956 with 25 workers as a group of mainly industrial worker

owned enterprises, today Mandragon comprises 250 coops, subsidiaries and affiliated

organizations mostly in Europe and throughout the world (Arando, Gago, Jones & Kato,

2015). Mondragon’s success does not mean the public policy is not important in helping worker

coops be developed. Sometimes, as the previous example demonstrated, the creation of a strong

worker coop sector came first. It was only after worker coop success that public policy was

created to further increase the strength and number of worker coops (Adeler, 2014).

       The determinants for the entry of new worker coops in Spain were studied and found to

be primarily related to the supply of entrepreneurs and institutional factors (Diaz-Foncea &

Marcuello, 2014). There seems to be a combination of factors responsible for worker coop

development in these countries. Although Spain’s worker coop sectors developed with little to no

help from public policy, it was helped to develop and expand once policymakers began creating

worker coop friendly legislation.

       Regional determinants in Spain that influence the creation of worker coops were

compared with determinants influencing the creation of traditional capitalist firms.

                                                 9
Entrepreneurial demand and supply factors, as well as institutional environment factors, were

used as indicators to examine and compare firm creation opportunities. Results showed that

population growth, salary level and the unemployment rate have a positive and significant

influence on worker coop creation (Diaz-Foncea & Murceollo, 2015). The population increased

as did the level of unemployment. Unemployment proved to be the main determinant for the

creation of worker coops in Spain (Diaz-Foncea & Murceollo, 2015). This means that the higher

the unemployment rate was in a region of Spain, the greater the number of worker coops created

in that same region. High unemployment exists, however, in other countries and yet worker

coops are not being created there at the same rate as in Spain. Other studies on worker coops in

Spain point out that cooperation among cooperatives is the reason for a high worker coop

creation rate here and why the largest worker coop in the world, Mondragon, is located here

(Basterretxea, Charterina & Landeta, 2019). The worker coop creation ratio in Spain, when

compared to the rest of the world, is extremely high. Many entrepreneurs in Spain, for whatever

reason, choose the worker coop business model over conventionally owned firms. Further

research to determine all the reasons why there is an above-average worker coop firm creation

ration in Spain and not in other places like the US can help to discover barriers.

       Research on worker coops in France show they are overall successful in part due to

employee participation which reduces agency and information costs (Kispál-Vitai, Regnard,

Kovesi & Guillotte, 2019). Worker coops, like traditional businesses, are not perfect business

models but they are more efficient in the above-mentioned areas. Firm survival seems to be

correlated with greater employment stability inherent in worker coops. Having job security

makes it possible for workers to vote for actions that are not just good for them in the short term

but good for the organization in the long term (Burdin, 2014). Other studies have empirically

                                                 10
shown cooperatives to feature less managerial supervision compared to traditional firms

(Thompson, 2015). Management supervision may be more efficient in worker co-ops because

managers are elected by workers. In addition, each worker is also an owner of the business and

as such monitors themselves and others. More efficient management supervision saves time and

resources which gives worker coop firms an advantage over conventionally owned firms.

       Worker coops and traditional firms' use of technology in France were compared in a

study to determine if the worker coop business model is as productive. As of 2012, there were

2000 worker cooperatives in France which employed 47,000 people (Fakhfakh, Perotin & Gago,

2012). Compared with most countries, France has a bigger worker coop sector. Worker coops

here like in other countries are owned by employees who each have one vote regardless of the

share of capital they hold. French worker coops were found to be as productive or more

productive overall than traditional firms in most industries (Fakhfakh, Perotin & Gago, 2012).

The study also found that the technology used by traditional firms was not as efficient as the one

invested in worker coops. The authors believe that the existence of the incentive effects

associated with full employee ownership is a reason why French worker coops have invested

more in more efficient technology than traditionally owned firms.

       Favorable legislation played a decisive role in helping to create worker coops in Canada,

France and Hungary (Kispál-Vitai, Regnard, Kovesi & Guillotte, 2019). France and Hungary, for

example, created new cooperative legislation in 2014 and 2006 adding to previous coop

legislation that was last created in France in 1947 and in the late 19th century in Hungary

respectively (Kispál-Vitai et al, 2019). Canada also relatively recently created a general

cooperative law in 1998. These countries and others had existing legislation that was from the

earlier part of the 20th century and in some cases the 19th century. The wealth gap has grown to

                                                11
the point where the wealthiest 85 individuals own as much as the poorest 50% of humanity. This

trend, or second wave of renewed worker coop enthusiasm, is most likely a response to the

widening wealth gap and to economic instability.

U.S. States and Cities Developing Worker Cooperatives

       This chapter’s goal is to look at how cities in the US are using public policy to help

develop worker cooperatives. In the past public policy has been used to try to address systemic

challenges. Legislation is also important for worker coop creation not just in other countries but

in the US as well. In an effort to create more just and equitable markets, state and city

governments are increasingly adopting worker cooperatives initiatives and laws (Camou,

2016). The California AB 816 law amended cooperative law to help create a way for worker

coops to raise capital from their community (Jacob, 2016). Ten US cities, under the Imagine

Economy Project, used one of three approaches for worker cooperative development. This five-

year project is an effort to build up a worker coop ecosystem in each city taking part in this

project. The first two years of this project are meant for capacity building with the following 3

years meant more for delivering concrete expectations.

Anchor Institutions. One approach used in the Imagine Economy Project to support worker

coops seeks to gain procurement spending by area anchors institutions (Camou, 2016). Examples

of anchor institutions include hospitals, universities and medical institutions. Anchor institutions

are the largest employer in more than half of the top 100 most populated cities (Rogers, 2013). In

Cleveland, Ohio, for example, public policy was passed for the creation of a network of worker

coops designed to provide services to the local anchor institutions (Rowe, Peredo, Sullivan &

Restakis, 2017). Tying worker coops with local anchor institutions is a way to help ensure the

survival and development of worker coops in a city. The results of these municipal approaches to

                                                 12
worker coop development in these ten US cities are still in progress. Three of these cities have

implemented programs and projects that in turn have created 25 new worker coops in each city

that employ a total of 261 people (Camou, 2016).

Cost Per Job Ratio. Most if not all forms of businesses, organizations and individuals contain

inefficiencies. The efficiency of the worker coops business model has been documented by

several studies. For example, service sector jobs were created in some cities under the Imagine

Economy Project public. The costs per job created ranged from $7,143 to $100,000 (Camou,

2016). The ratio of $10,000:1 for public investment per job created was set as a goal. The lower

number involved no financing roll by the city and the high number involved a substantial

financial role by the city. Most worker coops created through this initiative tended to be small

ones. The cost per job ratio that each of these cities used to create these new positions was

relatively lower on average when compared with traditional firms. The lower than average cost-

per-job ratio demonstrates that the worker coop model is efficient. Burdin (2014) agrees that firm

survival seems to be correlated with greater employment stability inherent in worker coops.

Having job security makes it possible for workers to vote for actions that are not just good for

them in the short term but good for the organization in the long term (Burdin,

2014). Policymakers in other cities and states that are interested in efficiently creating and

retaining long term quality employment in their communities could study and implement the

parts of these pilot programs that would help improve their communities.

Private-Public Partnership. Studies have shown that the private-public partnership approach to

supplying infrastructure and public services has increased (Wang, Xiong & Zhu, 2017). Many

city governments, in an effort to develop worker coops, have developed contract bid preferences

for worker cooperatives (Camou,2016). Worker coops that are certified as able to meet city

                                                 13
procurement needs would get priority. The short-term goal of the Imagine Economy Project

program would be to increase the number of worker coops. The long-term goal is to create more

equitable and inclusive local economies. One challenge to worker coop development in these

cities included the impact of worker coop initiatives on the other small businesses. Many cities

still want to achieve a balance between social and business purposes.

Barriers to Worker Coop Development. Impediments or barriers to worker coop development

can make starting and maintaining these types of business more challenging. Negative stigmas

and efficiency concerns may serve to deter individuals from creating or working in and being a

part of a worker coop. Insufficient data and a lack of familiarity with the worker coop business

model may also act as barriers. If entrepreneurs or banks are not familiar with the worker coop

business model, then it follows that they will not be as likely to create worker coops or provide

financing. These and other issues combined can act as barriers to worker coop development.

Insufficient Data. Public policy regarding worker coops has not kept pace with the demand for

such legislation. Public policy sometimes, however, has to be created to keep up with the

increasingly new demands brought on by a growing and changing worker coop sector (Adeler,

2014). Policy makers, in some instances, have had a reactionary approach to worker coop

development. Policy makers, however, do not have sufficient data on how the worker coop

model can aid in creating viable businesses and employment in their communities. Determining

what kind of business model is more sustainable and efficient is not always easy to ascertain due

to the scant direct evidence on the mechanisms that account for performance gaps between

conventionally owned firms and worker coops (Arando et al., 2019). This lack of data and

knowledge is a significant barrier for policy makers, entrepreneurs and communities who want to

use the worker coop model.

                                                14
Negative Stigma. The belief or explanation as to why worker coops are not as numerous because

they are not as efficient as traditional capitalist enterprises is another barrier. Some studies have

sought to determine the validity of this negative viewpoint of worker coops by analyzing cities

that are supporting locally rooted and anchored economic development. In the city of San

Francisco, for example, it was found that money spent on local bookstores created about 45%

more economic activity and about 40% more local wages than investing the same amount of

money in chain bookstores (Rogers, 2013). One area where worker coops are not as efficient as

traditional capitalist firms, which they are proud of, is in extracting community wealth and

transferring that wealth out of the community. Keeping the economy local conforms to the

worker coop sustainability principle which is meant to help maintain and or restore the

community in which the firm is located.

Efficiency Concerns. Another case study on three types of business models was done that

compared compare their efficiency. These businesses ranged from worker coops, where most if

not all employees were part owners, limited cooperatives, where only some of the employees are

part owners, and conventional stores where employee ownership is zero. All of these are in the

supermarkets and hypermarkets, which are superstores that combine supermarkets with

department stores. One result found was that a small subgroup of hypermarkets that are worker

coops greatly outperformed conventional firms in having significantly faster sales growth

(Arando, Gago, Jones & Kato, 2015). However, for supermarkets, there was no significant

performance among these three types of business models. Sustainability, as previously

mentioned, is a fundamental worker coop principle.

Ease of Transporting or Replicating. The ease of transporting or replicating the success of a

particular worker coop from one community to another has also been cited as another barrier to

                                                  15
promoting the worker coop model. Cooperativization is another term used when discussing the

replicability or diffusion of the worker coop model (Bretos et al., 2019). Replicability is exactly

what the Evergreen Cooperative Corporation set out to create when it first started in Cleveland,

Ohio shortly after the 2008 global financial crisis. Evergreen is a network of worker-owned

cooperatives meant to be replicable in any city and state offering sustainable greenhouse foods

(Rowe, Peredo, Sullivan & Restakis, 2017). An extensive study on Evergreen was done and the

primary finding stated that the Evergreen model might not be replicable because its development

depended heavily on contextual factors. Evergreen, for instance, was gifted millions of dollars to

help it start up (Rowe, Peredo, Sullivan & Restakis, 2017). This was done because banks

hesitated in giving Evergreen loans and worker coop public policy was inadequate.

Corporate Competition. Agricultural producers in France, Hungary and Canada formed

cooperatives also had similar contextual challenges. Challenges agricultural cooperatives faced

here were the industrialization of agriculture, shrinking natural resources and competition from

sizable firms (Kispál-Vitai, Regnard, Kovesi & Guillotte, 2019). Similarly, Evergreen’s

greenhouse agricultural foods sector needed a three million dollar donation to start up. The lack

of replicability here is not due to an inherent flaw within the worker coop model. The

survivability and sustainability of worker coops were compared with conventional firms in a

long panel of Uruguayan firms. Results showed that worker coops had a 29% lower hazard rate,

which means that coops have a longer survival time than conventional firms (Burdin,

2014). Worker coops prove they are sustainable if 29% of them remain in business longer than

conventional firms. However, corporate farming is a considerable challenge due to its large-scale

agriculture that makes it difficult for agricultural worker coops to compete.

                                                 16
Little to No Supporting Public Policy. Existing public policy or a lack of it undoubtedly is

another key determinant for worker coop creation. Literature and research on the obstacles and

constraints worker coops face are mostly in agreement in their results that a lack of adequate

policies and legislation disadvantage coops in competing with traditional capitalist enterprises

(Adeler, 2014). Policy here is defined as decisions made in a transparent and accountable manner

that result in actions or plans to facilitate worker coop creation (Saleh & Hamzah, 2017). This

study focuses on factors that facilitate and hinder the development of RE coops. A study

regarding wind power cooperatives in Denmark, Germany, Belgium and the UK analyzed the

reasons for the development of this energy community. The conclusion demonstrated that a

hostile environment, specifically externally imposed regulatory changes, for coops resulted in

coordinated actions amongst these RE coops (Bauwens, Gotchev & Holstenkamp, 2016).

Denmark, Germany, Belgium and the UK existing public policy on worker coops financing

proved to be the most important factor that enabled the establishment of many new energy coops

(Wierling et al., 2018). Results also showed that removing financial incentives and other support

schemes resulted in a dramatic downturn in the creation of new energy coops across all

countries. This illustrates how public policy can increase the obstacles, deliberately or not, that

worker coops face.

Education. Education is another challenge for worker co-ops. In Hungary, for example, the

word cooperative was associated with oppression and enforced joint work during the years of

communist central planning (Kispál-Vitai, Regnard, Kovesi & Guillotte, 2019). Education, in

some European countries, is needed to help destigmatize and disassociate the word cooperative

from the Soviet Union’s version of this. Worker coops, solidarity and cooperation are not part of

                                                 17
what is taught in mainstream economics (Miller, 2010). This illustrates one way how education

needs to be changed to remove obstacles to worker coop development.

Unfamiliarity with the Worker Coop Business Model. A lack of knowledge about the worker

coop model by current business owners is another barrier to worker coop development. Since

mainstream economics does not cover alternative business models well, creating spaces that

educate on worker coops is key for knowledge and skill sharing. In the US the lack of business

succession plans is the main cause of preventable job loss (Rogers, 2013). Educating business

owners and policy makers about the cooperative business model could help to mitigate job loss.

This is especially true since studies have found that worker coop principles have a positive

influence on the performance of a business in terms of both sales and employment growth

(Guzman, Santos & Barroso, 2019). Several cities have begun providing worker co-op education

to city government policy makers (Camou, 2016). This is an acknowledgment that worker coops

are unfamiliar to most people and that this must change if city worker coop initiatives are going

to succeed.

Conversions. Conversions, which entail changing existing traditional investor-owned and

conventionally owned firms into worker coops, has proven to be a challenge. Cultural values in

the institutional environment play a significant role in helping worker coops avoid converting

into traditional firms despite operational difficulties (Kispál-Vitai, Regnard, Kovesi & Guillotte,

2019). This means that despite the problems present in worker coops people do not want to

change them into traditional firms. An estimated 70% of privately-owned businesses in the US

will most likely change ownership in the next 10 years (Rogers, 2013). The vast majority of

these businesses are traditional firms. Education about worker coops could target these owners.

                                                18
This could potentially make millions of privately-owned traditional firms convert into worker

coops. Public policy could be created to educate aging business owners on this option.

Financing. Financing can be a barrier for many type of business models but it is especially

problematic for the worker coop model. Cooperatives usually use debt financing, which is easier

to obtain but is more expensive than equity (Limnios, Watson, Mazzarol & Soutar, 2016).

Financing for worker coops, from 2002 to 2012, declined 10% as a percentage of all business

commercial bank lending (Rogers, 2013). Banks are decreasing the number of loans, for

whatever reasons, to worker coops. This is important because worker coops often find sources of

funding harder to secure because the coop structure makes external profit-driven investment

impossible (Miller, 2010). Banks are often hesitant to lend to worker-owned businesses and in

particular to work cooperatives because of the lack of familiarity with those models in

mainstream banking (Rogers, 2013). Credit access is significant because small businesses mostly

rely on bank loans to start up or survive whereas large businesses can raise money in the stock or

bond market. City governments could create policy here to at minimum bridge this gap.

       Some US cities representatives expressed that the lack of underwriting was the main

challenge worker co-ops faced in acquiring bank loans (Camou, 2016). Australian legislation,

Cooperative Capital Unit (CCU), was designed to provide greater flexibility for worker coops to

raise funds (Limnios et al., 2016). One-member-one-vote was changed to the one-share-one-vote

control structure in the hopes of attracting investors. As mentioned before, debt financing is

much more expensive than financing with equity.

Governing Boards and Management. Research on why worker coops in some countries fail

seeks to determine if this is due to worker coop management and or their governing boards. One

study analyzed the nature of governance practices of coops in Malaysia which has a huge

                                                19
disparity between successful and less successful coops. Results indicated that governing board

incompetency was the reason for inefficiency and why many coops failed (Saleh & Hamzah,

2017). As previously stated, one of the coop ideals is democratic member control. Board

appointments based on member votes often get unqualified directors being appointed because of

a lack of worker training and education (Baskaran, 2015). Training and education are needed

because most workers come from an employment situation where they executed simple routine

jobs. In worker coops, employees have to manage a business collaboratively and be invested in

the continued growth of the business. This can result in an inability of the board to serve the

members and the local community interests (Baskaran, 2015). Whether the inability to appoint

qualified board members was due to a member’s character or ability or to other outside factors

was not determined in this study (Saleh & Hamzah, 2017). However, appointing unqualified

board members is most likely due to a combination of outside factors and to a member’s

character or ability.

Limitations

        Existing research on why the multinational expansion of worker coops has failed to

replicate worker coops that adhere to their key principles is overall limited (Arando et al., 2019).

Some studies claim that the worker coop model itself is the main reason for the difficulty in

replicating itself while other studies find that institutional differences at the regulatory level

between the worker coop country of origin and the subsidiary’s country of origin are the main

obstacle (Bretos, Errasti & Marcuello, 2019). Other literature gaps detected were tax breaks and

the benefit from the ease of financing that traditional firms get compared to worker coops

(Limnios, Watson, Mazzarol & Soutar, 2016). Learning more about the difficulties that worker

coops go through in attaining bank loans is critical to understanding why worker coops are

                                                  20
underrepresented. The reasons why banks do not usually give loans to worker coops, whether it

be due to unfamiliarity with the business model or other reasons, need to be studied further.

Literature Review Summary

       As mentioned above worker coops have been compared to traditional firms. Overall, the

literature is clear that the worker coops offer a legitimate alternative to the business model

(Camou, 2016). Much of the research shows that worker coops can compete with traditional

firms and or surpass them (Fakhfakh et al., 2012). However, it is clear that there are many

obstacles facing worker coops (Arando et al., 2019). These include unfamiliarity with the worker

coop model itself as well as financing (Limnios et al., 2016). Public policy and mainstream

economics mostly favor traditional firms which creates disadvantages for worker coops (Rogers,

2013). This, however, seems to be changing as entrepreneurs and policy makers are looking at

alternatives for job creation in response to recent economic downturns (Kispál-Vitai et al., 2019).

An increasing number of cities and states are creating a private-public partnership approach to

supplying infrastructure and public services has (Wang et al., 2017). However, there remains a

lack of research on the impediments to worker coop creation in the U.S.

                                                 21
Research Question and Aim

       What are the internal and external factors that impede the development of worker

cooperatives in different sectors?

       The purpose of this project is to explore the factors that condition the start-up of worker

coops which can then be used to identify policy options that will support worker coop

development in the U.S.

       Reporting on the results of this study could be used by public policy makers and other

individuals to create worker coops and help develop current worker coops. The end goal of the

project is to identify the barriers that impede worker coop development in the US to assist policy

makers in creating laws that sustain local communities by helping create and maintain good

quality jobs.

                                                22
Research Design

General Approach

       The purpose of this study is to determine the obstacles worker cooperatives in different

sectors face and how these determine the extent to which these affect worker coop creation and

expansion. An exploratory approach is the method chosen to collect qualitative and quantitative

data for this project. This method is appropriate since there is relatively little research on the

external and internal factors that impede the development of worker coops in different sectors

(Silverman, 2013). This study will focus on worker coops throughout the world that are in

different economic sectors. Surveys and interviews will be implemented in the method sampling.

Methods

       A stratified random sample was used to divide worker coops into their specific economic

sector. Five worker coops will be used for this project. One primary sector worker coop is in

agriculture. Another worker coop is a brewery which is part of the manufacturing sector. The

three other worker coops are in the service sector and are in retail, restaurant and medical

services. This is how eligible participants will be determined for recruitment. The sample size

will include one manager from each of these five worker co-ops. Managers will be selected in all

five sectors because managers have more experience with worker coops. This is because

managers have worked in a variety of positions inside the firm and as such may have more

insight. Each manager will undergo a semi-structured interview over the phone at their

convenience. Letting managers choose their interview date and time was done to allow them to

collect their thoughts and take their time.

Qualitative Data Collection. Qualitative interview questions will be relatable and will allow

participants to share their knowledge about what works or needs improvement in their worker

                                                  23
coops. Interview questions will be closed-ended. This will make the data retrieved more useful

for researchers because it will be less difficult to interpret and analyze.

       Interviewing management only was done because their position makes them more

familiar with the problems worker coop models have in starting up, staying competitive and in

business. Worker coop managers in different sectors will share their insight concerning the

obstacles to creating and maintaining worker coops. Management have more direct experience

with the strategies developed to solve their worker coop barriers and the degree to which these

strategies were successful. The goal of the interviews is to allow for the inquiry on how worker

coops internal processes affect their relationship with external stakeholders. See Appendix A for

the type of questions asked in the interview.

Quantitative Data Collection. In addition to being interviewed, each of the five managers will

be given a quantitative questionnaire that will assess the level of obstacles for maintaining their

particular worker coop business. The survey questions are closed-ended. Close-ended questions,

although not entirely perfect, help in assuring appropriateness by avoiding inserting biased

questions. Participants will be asked about what they have seen to be obstacles for their worker

coop creation and development. These particular questions were included in the questionnaire to

help determine the accuracy of the findings from the sources reviewed in this literature. This

questionnaire will help determine the validity of the findings cited in this project concerning

worker coop external barriers. External variables mentioned in the survey include financing.

Financing is operationalized here to include bank loans, credit, investors, government grants and

tax breaks. The questionnaire can also be used to determine the accuracy and extent to which

internal factors act as a barrier to worker coop efficiency. Internal factors placed in the

questionnaire include decision making which encompasses, member voting, management and the

                                                  24
governing board. Questionnaire data will be able to be used directly towards answering the

research question which seeks to reveal the internal and external factors that impede worker coop

development. See Appendix B below for the examples of survey questions asked.

                                               25
Discussion

Limitations

         Despite keeping the questions on the survey open-ended qualitative data due to its nature

can become biased. Participants interviewed, since they still are managers, may provide answers

that downplay problems in the internal workings of worker coops. Participates may also provide

overly positive feedback about their own firm’s ability to mitigate these problems. The research

for this project will not rely on evidence from existing studies, since this specific research

comparing the obstacles that worker coops from different sectors face is not available, and as

such will avoid creating a confirmation bias. The results here are generalizable because worker

coops from various economic sectors are included in this project. However, the generalizability

of these findings may be a limitation due to the low number of worker coops included in this

study.

Ethical Considerations

         Participation in this study is strictly voluntary. A privacy and confidentiality agreement

will be provided to participants. The nature and purpose of the study will be explained. Any

questions or concerns that potential participants have will be addressed before the study. At that

point, each individual will decide whether he or she wants to become a participant and, if so,

provide their informed consent. The researcher will make sure not to influence participants'

interviews and survey responses. The researcher will also make sure to report all findings to all

participants.

Expected Benefits/Contributions

  The results of this type of research can be beneficial in many ways. Analyzing the answers

will help determine worker coop barriers that current firms are experiencing which will

                                                  26
ultimately help to answer this project’s research question. The findings here can help future and

present worker coops to navigate and mitigate the obstacles that the participants mentioned. It

can help these business owners compete with traditionally owned and managed firms. This will

help worker coops stay solvent and avoid having to file for bankruptcy. Successful worker coops

can also help keep wages in the community, since most worker coops are small, and help create

sustainable communities. Public policy makers can also benefit from learning about what inhibits

worker coops from competing on an even playing field with traditional firms and as such can use

this data to help promote worker coop friendly legislation that helps create living-wage jobs for

their constituents.

                                                27
Conclusion

       Due to the relative rareness of worker coops in existence, a low number of these were

included in this study. The generalizability of our findings is a limitation due to the small number

of worker coops included in this study. In addition, due to the low number of worker coops

included in this study, future research might include many more worker coops found in every

sector in the US and also throughout the world. The increasing depth and length of economic

downturns have generated more interest in alternative business models such as worker coops. As

is sometimes the case, public policy is created in response to grassroots efforts by local

communities seeking new political and economic paths and directions (Diaz-Foncea &

Marcuello, 2014). More needs to be done in the educational aspect as education can very well

prove to be the key in helping worker coops proliferate. Current and future business owners,

banks, investors and policy makers will not gravitate towards this business model if they are

unaware of its existence or its benefits. Others, such as people who lived in the Soviet Union

bloque and for who the words worker coops are associated with forced labor, need reassurance

that the current worker coop structure does not include forced or free labor. Including worker

coops from various sectors of the economy in this study helps to give it generalizability. Public

policy has generally not helped create a strong worker coop sector. Examples of public policy

that could be used to develop worker coops are favorable taxation and funding instruments. The

proposed exploratory research here includes an interview and questionnaire that will be used to

obtain the required data. The findings here can be used by policymakers, entrepreneurs and

others to help sustain local communities by creating quality employment opportunities.

                                                 28
References

Adeler, M. (2014). Enabling Policy Environments for Co-operative Development: A

       Comparative Experience. Canadian Public Policy / Analyse De Politiques, 40, S50-S59.

Arando, S., Gago, M., Jones, D. C., & Kato, T. (2015). Efficiency in employee-owned

       enterprises: An econometric case study of Mondragon. ILR Review, 68(2), 398-425.

Artz, Georgeanne M. and Kim, Younjun, "Business ownership by workers: Are worker

       cooperatives a viable option?" (2011). Economics Working Papers (2002–2016). 99.

Baskaran, P. (2015). Introduction to Worker Cooperatives and Their Role in the

       Changing Economy. Journal of Affordable Housing & Community Development Law,

       24(2), 355-381.

Basterretxea, I., Charterina, J., & Landeta, J. (2019). Coopetition and innovation.

       Lessons from worker cooperatives in the Spanish machine tool industry. Journal of

       Business & Industrial Marketing.

Bauwens, T., Gotchev, B., & Holstenkamp, L. (2016). What drives the development of

       community energy in Europe? The case of wind power cooperatives. Energy Research &

       Social Science, 13, 136-147.

Beamish, P. W., & Lupton, N. C. (2016). Cooperative strategies in international business and

       management: Reflections on the past 50 years and future directions. Journal of World

       Business, 51(1), 163-175.

Blum, J. K. (2017). A Clean Break: Fuerza Laboral's Quest to Incubate a Cleaning Cooperative

       in Rhode Island (Doctoral dissertation, Tufts University).

Bretos, I., Errasti, A., & Marcuello, C. (2019). Multinational expansion of worker

                                                29
cooperatives and their employment practices: Markets, institutions, and politics in

       Mondragon. ILR Review, 72(3), 580-605.

Burdín, G. (2014). Are worker-managed firms more likely to fail than conventional

       enterprises? Evidence from Uruguay. ILR Review, 67(1), 202-238.

Camou, M. (2016). Cities developing worker co-ops: Efforts in ten cities. Imagine

       Economy Project.

Chowdhury, A. (2018). Inequality and Its Discontents. Development, 61(1-4), 21-29.

Díaz-Foncea, M., & Marcuello, C. (2015). Spatial patterns in new firm formation: Are

       cooperatives different? Small Business Economics, 44(1), 171-187.

Fakhfakh, F., Perotin, V., & Gago, M. (2012). Productivity, Capital and Labor in

       Labor-Managed and Conventional Firms: An Investigation of French Data.

       Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 65(4), 847-879.

Grace, D. (2014). Measuring the Size and Scope of the Cooperative Economy: Results of the

       2014. Global Census on Co-operatives. United Nation’s Secretariat Department of

       Economic and Social Affairs Division for Social Policy and Development.

Guzmán, C., Santos, F. J., & Barroso, M. D. L. O. (2019). Analysing the links between

       cooperative principles, entrepreneurial orientation and performance. Small

       Business Economics, 1-15.

Jacob, S. (2016). California unveils new law to jumpstart worker co-ops. Rural

       Cooperatives, 83(2), 22-25.

Kispál-Vitai, Z., Regnard, Y., Kövesi, K., & Guillotte, C. A. (2019). Cooperative case

       studies from three countries: Is membership a problem or a solution in the 21st

       century?. Society and Economy, 41(4), 467-485.

                                               30
Landín, S. (2018). The scarcity of worker cooperatives in the USA: Enquiring into possible

       causes. CIRIEC - Espana, (92), 39-60.

Limnios, E. M., Watson, J., Mazzarol, T., & Soutar, G. (2016). Financial instruments and equity

       structures for raising capital in co-operatives. Journal of Accounting and Organizational

       Change, 12(1), 50-74.

Miller, E. (2010). Solidarity economy: Key concepts and issues. Solidarity economy I:

       Building alternatives for people and planet, 25-41.

Olsen, E. K. (2013). The relative survival of worker cooperatives and barriers to their creation.

       Sharing Ownership, Profits, and Decision-Making in the 21st Century (Advances in the

       Economic Analysis of Participatory and Labor-Managed Firms, 14, 83-107.

Rogers, J. (2013). Using state and local policies. The Good Society, 22(1), 91-109.

Rowe, J. K., Peredo, A. M., Sullivan, M., & Restakis, J. (2017). Cooperative

       Development, Policy, and Power in a Period of Contested Neoliberalism: The

       Case of Evergreen Cooperative Corporation in Cleveland, Ohio.

Saleh, N. M., & Hamzah, N. (2017). Co-operative Governance and the Public Interest:

       Between Control and Autonomy. Jurnal Pengurusan (UKM Journal of

       Management), 51.

Silverman, D. (2013). Doing qualitative research: A practical handbook. SAGE publications

       limited.

Thompson, S. (2015). Towards a social theory of the firm: worker cooperatives

       reconsidered. Journal of Co-operative Organization and Management, 3(1), 3-13.

Wang, H., Xiong, W., Wu, G., & Zhu, D. (2018). Public–private partnership in public

                                                31
You can also read