2020 ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF HIGH PUBLIC DEBT: EVIDENCE FROM THREE LARGE SCALE DSGE MODELS - Banco de España
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF HIGH PUBLIC DEBT: EVIDENCE FROM THREE 2020 LARGE SCALE DSGE MODELS Documentos de Trabajo N.º 2029 Pablo Burriel, Cristina Checherita-Westphal, Pascal Jacquinot, Matthias Schön and Nikolai Stähler
ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF HIGH PUBLIC DEBT: EVIDENCE FROM THREE LARGE SCALE DSGE MODELS
ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF HIGH PUBLIC DEBT: EVIDENCE FROM THREE LARGE SCALE DSGE MODELS (*) Pablo Burriel BANCO DE ESPAÑA Cristina Checherita-Westphal and Pascal Jacquinot ECB Matthias Schön and Nikolai Stähler BUNDESBANK (*) This paper was part of an ESCB background paper to the 2017 Public Finance Report. In that context, we would like to thank our co-authors on that paper: Maria Campos (Banco de Portugal), Francesco Caprioli and Pietro Rizza (Banca d’Italia) and Alexander Mahle (Bundesbank), as well as Frank Smets, Claudia Braz, Christophe Kamps, Thomas Warmedinger, Philipp Rother, Samuel Hurtado and the members of the ESCB Working Group on Public Finance for their useful comments and suggestions. We are also grateful to an anonymous referee for very useful comments and suggestions on the ECB working paper. Any remaining errors are ours. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the European Central Bank or the ESCB Working Group on Public Finance and its members. This paper has also been published as an ECB Working Paper with number 2450, July 2020. Documentos de Trabajo. N.º 2029 2029
The Working Paper Series seeks to disseminate original research in economics and finance. All papers have been anonymously refereed. By publishing these papers, the Banco de España aims to contribute to economic analysis and, in particular, to knowledge of the Spanish economy and its international environment. The opinions and analyses in the Working Paper Series are the responsibility of the authors and, therefore, do not necessarily coincide with those of the Banco de España or the Eurosystem. The Banco de España disseminates its main reports and most of its publications via the Internet at the following website: http://www.bde.es. Reproduction for educational and non-commercial purposes is permitted provided that the source is acknowledged. © BANCO DE ESPAÑA, Madrid, 2020 ISSN: 1579-8666 (on line)
Abstract The paper reviews the economic risks associated with regimes of high public debt through DSGE model simulations. The large public debt build-up following the 2009 global financial and economic crisis acted as a shock absorber for output, while in the recent and more severe COVID19-crisis, an increase in public debt is even more justified given the nature of the crisis. Yet, once the crisis is over and the recovery firmly sets in, keeping debt at high levels over the medium term is a source of vulnerability in itself. Moreover, in the euro area, where monetary policy focuses on the area-wide aggregate, countries with high levels of indebtedness are poorly equipped to withstand future asymmetric shocks. Using three large scale DSGE models, the simulation results suggest that high- debt economies (1) can lose more output in a crisis, (2) may spend more time at the zero- lower bound, (3) are more heavily affected by spillover effects, (4) face a crowding out of private debt in the short and long run, (5) have less scope for counter-cyclical fiscal policy and (6) are adversely affected in terms of potential (long-term) output, with a significant impairment in case of large sovereign risk premia reaction and use of most distortionary type of taxation to finance the additional debt burden in the future. Going forward, reforms at national level, together with currently planned reforms at the EU level, need to be timely implemented to ensure both risk reduction and risk sharing and to enable high debt economies address their vulnerabilities. Keywords: government debt, interest rates, economic growth, fiscal sustainability. JEL classification: E62, H63, O40, E43.
Resumen En este trabajo se analizan los efectos sobre la actividad económica derivados de mantener un nivel elevado de deuda pública por medio de simulaciones realizadas con modelos de equilibrio general dinámico estocástico (DSGE, por sus siglas en inglés). La fuerte acumulación de deuda pública tras la crisis económica y financiera global de 2009 contribuyó a moderar el impacto de la perturbación sobre la actividad. Esta respuesta de política económica está más justificada, si cabe, ante la pandemia de Covid-19, por el marcado carácter transitorio de la perturbación. No obstante, en el medio plazo, una vez se haya superado el impacto inmediato de la pandemia y la recuperación económica esté firmemente asentada, mantener niveles tan elevados de deuda pública puede suponer una fuente de vulnerabilidad para la economía. Esta cuestión es aun más relevante en el caso del área del euro, donde la política monetaria responde al comportamiento de variables agregadas del conjunto del área, de forma que los países con elevados niveles de deuda no cuentan con este instrumento de política para responder a perturbaciones asimétricas. Los resultados de las simulaciones obtenidas a partir de tres modelos DSGE, estimados o calibrados con datos del área del euro, sugieren que las economías con elevada deuda pública: 1) experimentan caídas de la actividad más profundas durante una crisis; 2) pueden pasar más tiempo en la cota inferior de los tipos de interés nominales; 3) muestran efectos spillover negativos entre economías más intensos; 4) producen una mayor expulsión de deuda privada en el corto y el largo plazo; 5) presentan una capacidad para realizar una política contracíclica menor, y 6) sufren mayores pérdidas de producto potencial, especialmente cuando la prima de riesgo reacciona significativamente y cuando se financia el coste futuro de la mayor carga de deuda aumentando los impuestos más distorsionadores. De cara al futuro, para facilitar que las economías con elevado nivel de deuda puedan reducir sus vulnerabilidades, resulta necesario implementar reformas estructurales a escala nacional, y que las reformas de la Unión Europea, actualmente en discusión, permitan moderar los riesgos actuales y aumenten el grado de compartición de riesgos entre los miembros de la Unión. Palabras clave: deuda pública, tipos de interés, crecimiento económico, sostenibilidad fiscal. Códigos JEL: E62, H63, O40, E43.
Non-technical summary Debt – public and private – plays an important role in the normal functioning of a market economy. In the private sector, credit is essential to facilitate investment and growth over time. In both the public and private sector, debt can have beneficial effects in terms of smoothing consumption and financing lumpy productive investment. The 2009 global financial and economic crisis left a legacy of historically high levels of public debt in advanced economies, at a scale unseen during modern peace time. Given the extreme severity of the crisis, coined by many as the “great recession”, this debt build-up acted as a shock absorber for output. The coronavirus (COVID-19) pandemic is a different type of shock that has dramatically affected global economic activity, including the euro area, since early 2020. Fiscal positions are projected to be strongly hit by the crisis through both automatic stabilisers and discretionary fiscal measures. This substantial support from fiscal policy, together with that of monetary policy, is necessary and should help limit the economic scars of the crisis. Yet, once the crisis is over and the recovery firmly sets in, keeping public debt at high levels over the medium term is a source of vulnerability in itself. A high public debt burden is even more problematic in the euro area, as fiscal policies remain at national level while monetary policy focuses on the aggregate. The main objective of this paper is to contribute to the stabilisation vs. sustainability debate in the euro area by reviewing through the lens of large scale DSGE models the economic risks associated with regimes of high public debt. The paper argues that a good balance between the two fiscal policy objectives is difficult to achieve when public debt is high. To this end, we first review the theoretical and empirical literature on the role and macroeconomic consequences of public debt. Thereafter, we evaluate the economic consequences of high public debt using simulations with three DSGE models that share the same new-Keynesian framework and feature an enhanced government sector: EAGLE – E(S)CB, GEAR – Bundesbank, and BE – Banco de España. To our knowledge, this paper is one of the first to systematically assess the macroeconomic implications of high public debt in a global DSGE setup designed for the euro area. By using three different models widely employed for policy simulations in our institutions, we aim at providing a robust and encompassing analysis for the euro area. First, we explicitly account for the heterogeneity within the euro area. The models are calibrated or estimated for different regions/countries, with the euro area being split into either core vs. periphery (for EAGLE and the BE model) or Germany vs. the rest of the EA (for GEAR). Second, and, more crucially, the three models enrich our analysis by bringing alternative perspectives. Hence, the EAGLE model features a more detailed euro area and external block, GEAR includes a sound labour market, while the BE model has a financial block with borrowing constrains and long-term debt. Third, we are able to design a broad range of simulation scenarios, which shed light into various risks associated with regimes of high debt. Hence, we can assess the macroeconomic consequences of an excessive level of debt when the economy is hit by an adverse shock, in normal times or at the zero lower bound (ZLB). In addition, using the BE model, we can examine the specific role played by private deleveraging. Finally, a set of simulations evaluate the long-term costs of a high debt burden. As indicated in the literature, first, high public debt poses significant economic challenges as it makes the economy less resilient to shocks; second, debt overhangs can exert adverse pressure on the economy through multiple channels over the long-run. Our DSGE simulations also suggest that high-debt economies (1) can lose more output in a crisis, (2) may spend more time at the zero-lower bound, (3) are more heavily affected by spillover effects, (4) face a crowding out of private debt in the short and long run, (5) have less scope for counter-cyclical fiscal policy and (6) are adversely affected in terms of potential (long-term) output, with a significant impairment in case of large sovereign risk premia reaction3 and use of most distortionary type of taxation to finance the additional public debt burden in the future. The strength of these results depends on the impact BANCO DE ESPAÑA of the level 7 DOCUMENTO ofN.ºpublic DE TRABAJO 2029 debt in these models. Given that the sovereign bond yield spread is the main transmission channel, in the short-run simulations results also depend crucially on the monetary policy implementation. Going forward, planned reforms at national and EU level to ensure both risk reduction and risk sharing
fiscal policy and (6) are adversely affected in terms of potential (long-term) output, with a significant impairment in case of large sovereign risk premia reaction and use of most distortionary type of taxation I. Introduction to finance the additional public debt burden in the future. The strength of these results depends on the impact of the level of public debt in these models. Given that the sovereign bond yield spread is the The 2009 global financial and economic crisis left a legacy of historically high levels of public debt in main transmission channel, in the short-run simulations results also depend crucially on the monetary advanced economies, at a scale unseen during modern peace time. Given the extreme severity of the policy implementation. crisis, coined by many as the “great recession”, this debt build-up acted as a shock absorber for output, through Going forward,the work of automatic planned reformsstabilisers, at nationalcosts and EUincurred level to in ensure the stabilisation both risk of the financial reduction sector, and risk and sharing fiscal to need stimulus be timelymeasures grantedtoatenable implemented the beginning high debt of the crisis. While economies reduce debttheir ratios had generallyOnce vulnerabilities. declined the in the euro area countries since that crisis, they still remained COVID-19 crisis is over and the economic recovery firmly re-established, further efforts to build at high and very high levels in some fiscal countries. buffers The coronavirus in good times and mitigate (COVID-19) fiscal pandemic risks over stroke the mediumthe global termeconomic are needed activity, at theincluding national in the level. euro At area, the–EU in early level, and the EU2020, as a recovery more severe fund currently and different type under negotiation of shock. Mainly is one economy. due important tool to the strict thatprivate lockdown may not only Debt private public – is integral to the functioning of a market In the sector, measures bolster implemented in most euro area countries around mid-March, euro area real GDP registered credit isthe foundation essential for sustainable to facilitate productive growth in the aftermath investment and growth of the over COVID-crisis, time. In both but the also public support high- and private a record debt decline countries to of 3.8% in address thevulnerabilities. their first quarter of 2020. According to Eurosystem staff’s macroeconomic sector, debt can have beneficial effects in terms of smoothing consumption and financing lumpy projections, a further decline in GDP of 13% is expected for the second quarter and what will happen investment. In most advanced economies, as well as in most macroeconomic models, 2 public debt has after that is subject to unprecedented uncertainty. 1 Fiscal positions are projected to be strongly hit by been perceived, at least before the 2009 crisis, to be safe (Coeuré 2016). When it carries low credit the crisis, through both automatic stabilisers and discretionary fiscal measures. This substantial support risk, by providing a relatively safe and liquid asset, also for refinancing operations, public debt plays a I. fromIntroduction vital fiscal policy, together with that of monetary policy, is necessary and should help limit the economic role for the functioning of the financial system and the transmission of monetary policy. Other scars of the crisis. contributions conclude that public debt can have positive effects on welfare as long as it provides a safe The asset 2009 global financial for insurance against and both economic idiosyncratic crisis leftaggregate a legacy ofrisks. historically high levels of public debt in aggregatedand 3 The general government debt ratio across euro area (EA) member countries rose from 66% advanced economies, at a scale unseen during modern peace time. Given the extreme severity of the of GDP in 2007 to 95% in 2014, slightly declining afterwards (to 86% by 2019), while total (public and crisis, Yet, when coineddebtbyismany as theit “great too high, recession”, may become riskythis for debt build-up acted the economy. as a shock Essentially, one absorber needs to for output, recognise private) debt peaked close to 240% of GDP in 2012 and declined to 223% by end-2018(Chart 1a). through the work debt that government of automatic even in stabilisers, advanced costs incurred economies, andin the stabilisation especially of the in those financialtosector, belonging monetary and Before the COVID-19 crisis hit, two euro area countries had public debt ratios above 120% of GDP at fiscal unions, stimulus measures is not risk free. A granted high public at thedebtbeginning burden is ofproblematic the crisis. While debt ratios especially had generally in a monetary uniondeclined like the end-2019 (Greece and Italy) and another four countries (Portugal, Belgium, France, Cyprus and Spain) in eurothearea, euro in area whichcountries fiscal since policies that crisis,atthey remain still remained national level, whileat high memberand very states highsharelevels in some a common above 90% (Chart 1b). According to the European Commission’s spring 2020 forecast, the euro area countries. currency and Thelackcoronavirus monetary(COVID-19) policy autonomy. pandemicIn thisstroke the global institutional set-up economic nationalactivity, including fiscal policies carryin the debt ratio would increase to 103% of GDP in 2020 and decline to 99% in the next year, while the above euro burden area, in early to adjust to2020, as a more asymmetric severe shocks. and different However, euro area typecountries of shock.with Mainly highdue to the levels of strict publiclockdown debt are mentioned countries will have higher debt ratios, with the largest increases by 2021 projected for Italy measures poorly equipped implemented to carryinout most thiseuro area countries stabilisation around task. Risks tomid-March, euro area debt sustainability in areal GDP registered member state can and a Spain record (countries decline mostinhard-hit by the pandemic). entail risks to theof 3.8% stabilisation theoffirst quarter the euro areaof as 2020. According to Eurosystem staff’s macroeconomic a whole. projections, a further decline in GDP of 13% is expected for the second quarter and what will happen The main objective Chartis1:toPublic and private debt in the euro area after that is subject of to this paper unprecedented contribute uncertainty. to 1the stabilisation Fiscal positionsvs. aresustainability projected todebate be stronglyin thehit euro by area a) 4 by reviewing through total, public & the lens private debt of (%large of scale GDP) DSGE b) The models most the the crisis, through both automatic stabilisers and discretionary fiscal measures. This substantial support EA aggregate: publicly macroeconomic indebted countries in the implications EA (% of GDP) of high public debt. The paper argues that a good balance between the from fiscal policy, together with that of monetary policy, is necessary and should help limit the economic two fiscal policy objectives is 270 difficultoftothe scars achieve crisis. when public debt is high. 210 240 180 To210our The knowledge, general governmentthis paper debtisratio oneaggregated of the first toacross systematically euro areaassess(EA) member the macroeconomic countries rose implications from 66% of high of180 public debt in a global DSGE setup designed for 150 the GDP in 2007 to 95% in 2014, slightly declining afterwards (to 86% by 2019), while total (public and euro area. 5 private) 150 debt peaked close to 240% of GDP in 2012 120 and declined to 223% by end-2018(Chart 1a). The analysis is based on three different global DSGE models (EAGLE – E(S)CB, GEAR – Bundesbank, Before 120 the COVID-19 crisis hit, two euro area countries had public debt ratios above 120% of GDP at and BE - Banco de España) that share the same new-Keynesian 90 framework and feature an enhanced end-2019 90 (Greece and Italy) and another four countries (Portugal, Belgium, France, Cyprus and Spain) government sector. By using three different models widely employed for policy simulations in our above 60 90% (Chart 1b). According to the European Commission’s 60 spring 2020 forecast, the euro area institutions, we aim at providing a robust and encompassing analysis for the euro area. First, we debt ratio would increase to 103% of GDP in 2020 and decline to 99% in the next year, while the above explicitly 30 account for the heterogeneity within the euro30 area. The models are calibrated or estimated for mentioned countries will have higher debt ratios, with the largest increases by 2021 projected for Italy different 0 regions/countries, with the euro area being split 0 into either core vs. periphery (for EAGLE and and Spain (countries most hard-hit by the pandemic). 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 2021 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 the BE model) or Germany EA Public Debt vs. the rest of EA Private Debt the EA (for GEAR).GR Second, EA Total Debt IT and, PT more ES crucially, FR BE the three CY models enrich Debt – private and public –our analysis by bringing is integral alternative to the perspectives. The EAGLE model features a more Chart 1: Public andfunctioning private debtofinathe market euro economy. area In the private sector, detailed credit Source: is Eurostat, euro area essential European to(including Commissionfacilitate tradable productive (Ameco, Spring and 2020 forecast) andnon-tradable investment and own calculations. sectors)over growth andtime.symmetric In both external the public blockand (and private as Notes: Public a) EAdebtaggregate: stands for general government total, public &gross debt (EDP private debt concept), (% of as defined in the GDP) b) Ameco The database. most Privateindebted publicly debt standscountries for the stockinofthe liabilities EA held (% by the of GDP)sectors such corporations sector, Non-financial is very debt well and suited canHouseholds have and to assess beneficial international effects Non-Profit institutions serving spillovers), inhouseholds, terms GEAR data, as includes of smoothing consolidated perconsumption a sound the Macroeconomic labour and Imbalance market, financing procedure while for (MIP)lumpy scoreboard euro area Member States (latest data available for all countries as of end-2018). The EA private debt is calculated as the GDP-weighted average across the Member States. The the BE euro investment. area model has In most 270total debt is calculated a financial as theadvanced sum between theblock with economies, borrowing EA private debt and aspublic well as210in most macroeconomic models, 2 public debtlong- constrains debt. à la Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) and has term been debt. Third, we are able to design a broad range of simulation scenarios, which shed light into 240 perceived, at least before the 2009 crisis, to be safe (Coeuré 2016). When it carries low credit various risks associated with regimes of high debt. 180 Hence, risk, by providing a relatively safe and liquid asset, also for refinancing operations, public debt plays a we can assess the macroeconomic 210 vital 1 See role 180 for the June 2020 functioning Eurosystem of the financial staff macroeconomic system projections and for150the the euro transmission of monetary policy. Other area. contributions 2 Assuming a fullconclude that consolidation public between debt the can balance have sheet 4 ofpositive the central effects bank andonthat welfare as long of the fiscal as it provides authority, governmentadebt safeis 150 120 considered risk-free in nominal terms. For the euro area, in particular, institutional design like the prohibition of monetary asset for insurance against both idiosyncratic and aggregate 5 risks. 3 financing and the no bail-out clause (articles 123 and 125 of the EU Treaty) make such models unrealistic. 120 90 3 However, the literature on the relationship between public debt and welfare remains ambiguous, with several studies indicating Yet,90 a when debt negative is too impact high, of debt onitwelfare may become or optimalrisky for the debt levels economy. that are either Essentially, one needs very small or negative to recognise (government should 60 8 DOCUMENTO BANCO DE ESPAÑA60accumulate that government net DE assets). TRABAJO N.º This debt even 2029 is especially the case when welfare (asset holding) is concentrated on a minority of households in advanced economies, and especially in those belonging to monetary or when the government seeks to smooth tax distortion over time and thus needs asset buffers to offset adverse shocks. For unions, 30 is not a review, seerisk Dieppefree. andAGuardahigh public (2015). debt burden is problematic especially in a monetary union like the 30 euro 4 See area, 0 inter alia,inECB which fiscal (2016b), policies EC (2016), remainand Bańkowski at Ferdinandusse national0 level, while member states share a common (2017), IMF (2017). For more details on sustainability, 1999Boubabdallah see 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 et al. (2017). currency 5 and lack monetary policy autonomy. In this institutional set-up national fiscal policies carry the 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 2021
debt ratio would increase to 103% of GDP in 2020 and decline to 99% in the next year, while the above mentioned countries will have higher debt ratios, with the largest increases by 2021 projected for Italy and Spain (countries most hard-hit by the pandemic). Chart 1: Public and private debt in the euro area a) EA aggregate: total, public & private debt (% of GDP) b) The most publicly indebted countries in the EA (% of GDP) Debt – private and public – is integral to the functioning of a market economy. In the private sector, credit 270 is essential to facilitate productive investment 210 and growth over time. In both the public and private sector, Debt 240 – debt privatecan and have beneficial public – is effects integral to in the terms of smoothing functioning of a market consumption economy. and In thefinancing lumpy private sector, 180 investment. credit 210 In most is essential advancedproductive to facilitate economies, as well asand investment in most growth macroeconomic models, over time. In both 2 public the public anddebt has private been sector,perceived, debt can athave leastbeneficial before theeffects 2009 crisis, in to 150 terms be of safe (Coeuré smoothing 2016). When consumption it carries and low lumpy financing credit 180 risk, by providing investment. a relatively In most advancedsafe and liquid economies, asasset, well asalso for refinancing in most operations, macroeconomic public models, debtdebt 2 public plays a has 150 120 vital beenrole for the at perceived, functioning least before of the the financial 2009 crisis,system to beand safethe transmission (Coeuré 2016). of monetary When policy. it carries low Other credit 120 contributions risk, conclude by providing that public a relatively safe debt and can liquidhave positive asset, also 90 effects for on welfare refinancing as long as operations, it provides public a safe debt plays a 90 assetrole vital for insurance against both for the functioning idiosyncratic of the and aggregate financial system 60 and therisks. 3 transmission of monetary policy. Other 60 contributions conclude that public debt can have positive effects on welfare as long as it provides a safe Yet, 30 when debt is too high, it may become risky for 30 the economy. Essentially, one needs to recognise asset for insurance against both idiosyncratic and aggregate risks.3 that 0 government debt even in advanced economies, and especially in those belonging to monetary 0 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 unions, Yet, when is not debt risk is free. A high too high, public it may debt burden become risky for is problematic the economy. 1999 2001 2003 especially 2005 2007 in Essentially, 2009a monetary one needsunion 2011 2013 2015 to2017 like 2019 the recognise 2021 EA Public Debt EA Private Debt EA Total Debt GR IT PT ES FR BE CY euro government that area, in which debtfiscal evenpoliciesin advanced remaineconomies, at nationaland level, while member especially in thosestates belonging sharetoa monetary common Debt – is currency unions, private and not lackand risk public monetary free. A –policy high ispublic integral autonomy. debt toburden theInfunctioning this is problematic of a market institutional set-up especially economy. national in a In the fiscal monetary private policies union sector, carry like the Source: Eurostat, European Commission (Ameco, Spring 2020 forecast) and own calculations. credit Notes:burden is Public debt essential to adjust stands eurocorporations area, for general inandwhich to facilitate to asymmetric government fiscal gross productive shocks. debt policies (EDP investment However, concept), remain as defined euro in at national and the Ameco growth area database. level, over countries Private time. debt In stands both with highstates for the the levels stock ofpublic of liabilities and publiccommon held by private debt the are sectors Non-financial Households and Non-Profit institutions serving households, consolidated data,while as per themember Macroeconomic Imbalanceshare procedurea(MIP) scoreboard for sector, poorly euro area debt Memberequipped currency and States can lack (latest datahave carrybeneficial tomonetary available out for policy all countries effects this stabilisation autonomy. as inThe of end-2018). terms task. In this ofdebtsmoothing Risks isto institutional EA private debtset-up calculated as consumption sustainability the national in and a across fiscal GDP-weighted average financing member policies the Memberstate carrylumpy can States. the The euro area total debt is calculated as the sum between the EA private debt and public debt. investment. toInthe most advancedof economies, as well aas inarea most macroeconomic with highmodels,levels of public public debt debt has 2 entail burden risks to adjust tostabilisation asymmetric the euro shocks. area However, as euro whole. countries are poorly equipped to carry out this stabilisation task. Risks to debt sustainability in a member statecredit been perceived, at least before the 2009 crisis, to be safe (Coeuré 2016). When it carries low can The risk, main objectivea of by providing this paper relatively safeis andto contribute liquid asset, to the also stabilisation for refinancing vs. sustainability operations, public debatedebt in theplayseuro a 1 entail risks to the stabilisation of the euro area as a whole. See June 4 by 2020 area vital for Eurosystem role reviewing the functioning staff macroeconomic through theof lens the financial projections of large scale system forDSGE the euromodels and the area. the macroeconomic transmission of monetaryimplications policy. Other of high The publicobjective contributions main debt. concludeThe paper thatpaper of this argues public to that isdebt canahave contribute goodto balance positive between effects the stabilisation on vs. thesustainability welfare twoasfiscal long as policy objectives it provides debate in thea eurosafe is difficult asset4 by area fortoreviewing achieve when insurance against through public thedebt both isofhigh. idiosyncratic lens large scaleand 5aggregate DSGE models risks.3the macroeconomic implications of high public debt. The paper argues that a good balance between the two fiscal policy objectives is To Yet,our knowledge, when this high, debt is too paperitismay one of the first to systematically assess the macroeconomic implications difficult to achieve when public debtbecome is high. risky for the economy. Essentially, one needs to recognise of high that public debtdebt government in a even globalinDSGE setupeconomies, advanced designed forand theespecially euro area.in 5 those belonging to monetary unions, To is not risk free. our knowledge, A highispublic this paper one ofdebt burden the first is problematicassess to systematically especially in a monetary union the macroeconomic like the implications The analysis is based on three different global DSGE models (EAGLE –5 E(S)CB, GEAR – Bundesbank, euro of higharea, publicin debt which in a fiscal policies global DSGEremain at national setup designed for level, while the euro member states share a common area. and BE - Banco de España) that share the same new-Keynesian framework and feature an enhanced currency and lack monetary policy autonomy. In this institutional set-up national fiscal policies carry the government The analysis sector. is based Byon using three different three different modelsmodels widely(EAGLE employed for policy simulations in our burden to adjust to asymmetric shocks. global However, DSGE euro area countries – E(S)CB, with GEAR high levels of–public Bundesbank, debt are institutions, and BE - we aim Banco de at providing España) that a robust share the and encompassing same new-Keynesian analysis framework for and the euro featurearea. an First, we enhanced poorly equipped to carry out this stabilisation task. Risks to debt sustainability in a member state can explicitly account government for Bythe using heterogeneity within the euro area. The models arefor calibrated or estimated for entail risks tosector. the stabilisation ofthree different the euro area models widely as a whole. employed policy simulations in our different regions/countries, institutions, we aim at providing with thea euro robustareaandbeing split into either encompassing core vs. analysis forperiphery the euro (for EAGLE area. First, andwe the TheBE main explicitlymodel) account or for objective Germany ofthethis vs. the paper heterogeneity rest is to of thethe contribute within EA (for toeuro GEAR). the area. TheSecond, stabilisation and,calibrated more crucially, vs. sustainability models are debate inthe thethree or estimated euro for models area4 byenrich different our analysis reviewing throughwith regions/countries, by thebringing lenseuro the alternative of large beingperspectives. area scale DSGE eitherThe models split into the EAGLE core model features macroeconomic vs. periphery a more implications (for EAGLE andof detailed highBE the eurodebt. public model) area (including or The Germany papervs. tradable argues the rest and thatofanon-tradable good the EA balance sectors) (for GEAR). betweenand the symmetric Second, external two fiscal and, more policy block (and objectives crucially, the as threeis such models is very difficult to wellour achieve enrich suited when topublic analysis assess by debt international is high. bringing spillovers), alternative GEAR includes perspectives. The EAGLE a sound labour model market, features while a more the BE model detailed has a(including euro area financial tradable block withand borrowing constrains non-tradable à laand sectors) Kiyotaki and Moore symmetric (1997) external block and(andlong- as To ouris term such knowledge, debt. veryThird, wethisare well suited paper to able isto assess one of theafirst design international to broad systematically range ofGEAR spillovers), assess simulation theamacroeconomic scenarios, includes soundwhich labourshed implications market,lightwhile into of high various the public risks debt BE model has ainfinancial associated a global with DSGE blockregimes setup with of designed high debt. borrowing for Hence, the euro constrains area. à lawe 5 can assess Kiyotaki and Moorethe (1997) macroeconomic and long- term debt. Third, we are able to design a broad range of simulation scenarios, which shed light into The analysis is based on three different global DSGE models (EAGLE – E(S)CB, GEAR – Bundesbank, various Assuming risks associatedbetween with regimes of high debt. Hence, bank andwe can of theassess the macroeconomic BE - aBancofull consolidation de España) thatthe balance thesheet of the central that fiscal authority, government debt is 2 and share same new-Keynesian framework and feature an enhanced considered risk-free in nominal terms. For the euro area, in particular, institutional design like the prohibition of monetary government financing andsector. By using the no bail-out clausethree different (articles 123 and 125models widely of the EU Treaty)employed for policy make such models simulations in our unrealistic. institutions, we aimonattheproviding relationshipabetween robustpublic anddebtencompassing analysis for thewith euro 3 Assuming a full consolidation between the balance sheet of the central bank and that of the fiscal authority, government debt is 2 However, the literature and welfare remains ambiguous, severalarea. studiesFirst, we indicating considered a risk-freeofindebt negative impact nominal terms. For on welfare the euro or optimal area, debt in particular, levels institutional that are either designorlike very small the prohibition negative of monetary (government should explicitly financing accumulate account and the net forbail-out no assets). theThis heterogeneity clause (articles is especially within the123 caseand the euro of the area. 125welfare when EU The Treaty) (asset models make holding) issuch are modelscalibrated concentrated or estimated unrealistic. on a minority of householdsfor 3different or when regions/countries, the government seeks with to the smooth euro tax area distortionbeing over split time andinto thus either needs core asset vs. periphery buffers to offset (for adverseEAGLE shocks. and For However, the literature on the relationship between public debt and welfare remains ambiguous, with several studies indicating a aBEreview, negative see Dieppe impact of and debtGuarda (2015). optimal debt levels that are either very small or negative (government should on welfare the model) or Germany vs. theorrest of the EA (for GEAR). Second, and, more crucially, the three 4 Seeaccumulate inter alia, ECBnet assets). (2016b), ThisECis(2016), especially the case Bańkowski andwhen welfare (asset Ferdinandusse holding) (2017), IMFis(2017). concentrated For moreon details a minority of households on sustainability, models or when enrich the our governmentanalysis see Boubabdallah et al. (2017). seeks by to bringing smooth tax alternative distortion perspectives. over time and thus needs The EAGLE asset buffers tomodel features offset adverse a more shocks. For a review, see Dieppe and Guarda (2015). 5 detailed Andrés eteuro area al (2020) (including assess the role tradable of high debtand in anon-tradable monetary union sectors) and symmetric under an endogenous external fiscal limit block However, a la Bi (2012). (and as 4 Seetheinter alia, ECBof(2016b), introduction this novel ECfeature (2016), Bańkowski restricts and Ferdinandusse significantly the number of(2017), nominal IMFand(2017). For more real rigidities of details on sustainability, the model in comparison suchsee is to the very well Boubabdallah suited models usedetinal. to the(2017). assess current paper.international spillovers), GEAR includes a sound labour market, while 5the BE model has a financial block with borrowing constrains à la Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) and long- Andrés et al (2020) assess the role of high debt in a monetary union under an endogenous fiscal limit a la Bi (2012). However, termthedebt. introduction Third, of this we novel are able featuretorestricts design significantly a broadthe number range ofofsimulation nominal and scenarios, real rigidities of the model which in comparison shed light into BANCO DE ESPAÑA to 9theDOCUMENTO models used in the DE TRABAJO current paper. N.º 2029 6 various risks associated with regimes of high debt. Hence, we can assess the macroeconomic 6 2 Assuming a full consolidation between the balance sheet of the central bank and that of the fiscal authority, government debt is
of high public debt in a global DSGE setup designed for the euro area.5 The analysis is based on three different global DSGE models (EAGLE – E(S)CB, GEAR – Bundesbank, and BE - Banco de España) that share the same new-Keynesian framework and feature an enhanced government sector. By using three different models widely employed for policy simulations in our institutions, we aim at providing a robust and encompassing analysis for the euro area. First, we consequences explicitly account of for an the excessive level ofwithin heterogeneity debt when the eurothearea. economy is hit byare The models an calibrated adverse shock, in normal or estimated for times or at the zero lower bound (ZLB). In addition, using the BE model, we different regions/countries, with the euro area being split into either core vs. periphery (for EAGLE can examine the specific and role BE the played by private model) deleveraging. or Germany Finally, vs. the rest a set of the EAof(forsimulations GEAR). Second, evaluateand, the long-term costs the more crucially, of athree high debt burden. models enrich our analysis by bringing alternative perspectives. The EAGLE model features a more detailed euro area (including tradable and non-tradable sectors) and symmetric external block (and as The main results of our simulations are the following: (i) A high level of public debt makes the economy such is very well suited to assess international spillovers), GEAR includes a sound labour market, while more vulnerable to shocks (crises); (ii) High public debt prolongs the time spent at the ZLB; (iii) the BE model has a financial block with borrowing constrains à la Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) and long- International spillovers increase the time spent at the ZLB for the high debt economy; (iv) A higher level term debt. Third, we are able to design a broad range of simulation scenarios, which shed light into of public debt crowds-out private debt in the short and long run; (v) High public debt restricts the scope various risks associated with regimes of high debt. Hence, we can assess the macroeconomic for counter-cyclical fiscal policy; (vi) A high level of public debt affects adversely potential (long-term) consequences of an excessive level of debt when the economy is hit by an adverse shock, in normal output, with a significant impairment in case of large sovereign risk premia reaction and use of most times or at Assuming theconsolidation a full zero lowerbetween boundthe (ZLB). balance In addition, usingbank the and BE that model, we can examine the specific thesheet of the central of the fiscal authority, government debt is 2 distortionary type of taxation to finance additional debt burden in the future. roleconsidered played by private risk-free deleveraging. in nominal Finally, terms. For the euroa area, set ofin simulations evaluate particular, institutional the like design long-term costsofofmonetary the prohibition a high financing and the no bail-out clause (articles 123 and 125 of the EU Treaty) make such models unrealistic. debt burden. These results show that in the presence of high debt, both the stabilisation and the sustainability 3 However, the literature on the relationship between public debt and welfare remains ambiguous, with several studies indicating objectives a negative ofimpact national fiscal of debt policies on welfare or in the euro optimal area that debt levels arearemore eitherdifficult to attain very small in case or negative of a severe (government should Theaccumulate main results of ourThis net assets). simulations is especiallyare the the casefollowing: when welfare(i)(asset A high level isofconcentrated holding) public debt onmakes the a minority of economy households idiosyncratic or when the government seeks to smooth tax distortion over time and thus needs asset buffers to offset adverse shocks. the shock. The main explanation relates to the constraint of monetary policy against For more vulnerable to shocks (crises); (ii) High public debt prolongs the time spent at the ZLB; (iii) backdrop a review,ofsee theDieppe euro andarea institutional Guarda (2015). design, with the main channel being that of heightened sovereign International See inter and spillovers alia, ECB (2016b),increase EC (2016), the time spent Bańkowski andtheat the ZLB for Ferdinandusse the high (2017), IMF debt economy; (iv) on A higher level of(2017). For more details sustainability, 4 spreads uncertainty. These results fit into broader literature sovereign vulnerability, according of public debt crowds-out see Boubabdallah private debt in the short and long run; (v) High public debt restricts the scope et al. (2017). toAndrés whichethigher risk premia al (2020) assess and borrowing the policy; role of high costs can union spill over to other sectors or jurisdictions, especially (vi)debt in a monetary under an endogenous fiscal limitpotential a la Bi (2012). However, 5 for counter-cyclical fiscal A high level of public debt affects adversely (long-term) in integrated the introductioneconomic of this novelandfeaturemonetary unions. the restricts significantly Investors number ofmaynominalthus more and real easily rigidities question of the both the model in comparison output, to thewith models a significant impairment used in the current paper. in case of large sovereign risk premia reaction and use of most sustainability of fiscal policies of a sovereign with high debt burden, particularly when its fiscal track- distortionary type of taxation to finance the additional debt burden in the future. record and growth prospects are poor, as well as its capacity to effectively implement counter-cyclical 6 fiscal Thesepolicies resultsand show stabilise that inthe theeconomy. presence of high debt, both the stabilisation and the sustainability objectives of national fiscal policies in the euro area are more difficult to attain in case of a severe The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 reviews the theoretical and empirical literature on the idiosyncratic shock. The main explanation relates to the constraint of monetary policy against the macroeconomic impact of public debt, with a special focus on the channels through which high debt backdrop of the euro area institutional design, with the main channel being that of heightened sovereign can ultimately affect growth. Section 3 reports the simulation results and Section 4 concludes. spreads and uncertainty. These results fit into the broader literature of sovereign vulnerability, according to which higher risk premia and borrowing costs can spill over to other sectors or jurisdictions, especially in integrated economic and monetary unions. Investors may thus more easily question both the II. Related literature sustainability of fiscal policies of a sovereign with high debt burden, particularly when its fiscal track- record The and growth literature prospects on the are poor, as macroeconomic well as effects of itspublic capacity to in debt, effectively implement particular counter-cyclical the empirical literature, fiscal policies and stabilise the economy. suggests that debt overhangs can exert adverse pressure on the economy through multiple channels. 6 The paper First, a highisdebt structured as follows. burden makes Section more the economy 2 reviews the theoretical vulnerable and empirical to macroeconomic shocks.literature on the By restraining macroeconomic the impact of public room for counter-cyclical debt, fiscal withand policy a special throughfocus on the spillover channels effects to thethrough private which sector,high debt a public can ultimately affect growth. Section 3 reports the simulation results and Section 4 concludes. debt overhang can deepen volatility, restrain economic recovery or hurt the economy even in the short- run if aggressive consolidation needs to be implemented in recessions. High government borrowing requirements can make a country more prone to liquidity shocks and defaults. Perceived sovereign II. Related vulnerability, literature reflected in higher risk premia and borrowing costs, can spill over to other sectors or jurisdictions, especially in integrated economic and monetary unions. In particular, the “diabolic loop" The literature on the macroeconomic effects of public debt, in particular the empirical literature, between sovereign and bank credit risk through the so-called “balance sheet channel” was considered6 suggests that debt overhangs can exert adverse pressure on the economy through multiple channels. by many to be the hallmark of the sovereign debt crisis in the periphery of the euro area (Brunnermeier et al.,a2016). First, At the high debt same burden time,the makes through the more economy country-spillovers vulnerable tochannel, the materialisation macroeconomic of risks to shocks. By restraining sovereign the room for debt sustainability can counter-cyclical have fiscal adverse policy and implications not only through spillover for the effects to country concerned, the private sector, abut also public for other members of the monetary union. debt overhang can deepen volatility, restrain economic recovery or hurt the economy even in the short- run if aggressive consolidation needs to be implemented in recessions. High government borrowing requirements can make a country more prone to liquidity shocks and defaults. Perceived sovereign vulnerability, reflected in higher risk premia and borrowing costs, can spill over to other sectors or jurisdictions, especially in integrated economic and monetary unions. In particular, the “diabolic loop" 6 See also ECB (2016a) for a discussion of risks and vulnerabilities associated with regimes of high debt. between sovereign and bank credit risk through the so-called “balance sheet channel” was considered by many to be the hallmark of the sovereign debt crisis in the periphery of the euro area (Brunnermeier et al., BANCO DE ESPAÑA 10 2016). DOCUMENTOAt the same DE TRABAJO N.º 2029 7 time, through the country-spillovers channel, the materialisation of risks to sovereign debt sustainability can have adverse implications not only for the country concerned, but also for other members of the monetary union.
debt overhang can deepen volatility, restrain economic recovery or hurt the economy even in the short- run if aggressive consolidation needs to be implemented in recessions. High government borrowing requirements can make a country more prone to liquidity shocks and defaults. Perceived sovereign vulnerability, reflected in higher risk premia and borrowing costs, can spill over to other sectors or jurisdictions, especially in integrated economic and monetary unions. In particular, the “diabolic loop" between sovereign and bank credit risk through the so-called “balance sheet channel” was considered Second, by many to andberelated to theofabove, the hallmark the theoretical the sovereign debt crisis and empirical in the peripheryliterature of the suggests euro area that high debt (Brunnermeier burdens can ultimately impede long-term growth. 7 This is particularly the case when debt is contracted et al., 2016). At the same time, through the country-spillovers channel, the materialisation of risks to to finance unproductive sovereign debt sustainability expenses can haveor beyond adverse optimal (growth-maximising) implications not only for thelevels country of concerned, public capital butstock also (Checherita-Westphal et al., for other members of the monetary union. 2014). Moreover, the quality of a country’s institutional framework is also likely to affect the relationship between debt and growth, with particularly low growth performance in situations Second, and of high debttocoupled related the above,with poor institutions and the theoretical and empirical conversely, a cushioned literature impact suggests thatof high high debt in situations burdens canof very strong ultimately institutions impede long-term(Masuch growth. et al., 7 This2016). A long string is particularly the ofcaseresearch when debttendsistocontracted conclude that high public to finance debt can expenses unproductive adversely or affect growth beyond through optimal the channels of sovereign (growth-maximising) levels ofspreads (confidence public capital stock effects) and sovereignet yields, (Checherita-Westphal 6 See also ECB (2016a) for a 8 al., 2014). financial Moreover, intermediation the quality of(bank credit),institutional a country’s 9 higher future distortionary framework is also discussion of risks and vulnerabilities associated with regimes of high debt. taxation, 10 future crowding-out of private investment11 (debt is a deadweight burden on the economy), likely to affect the relationship between debt and growth, with particularly low growth performance in lower situationsscope for counter-cyclical of high debt coupled with fiscal poorpolicy, including institutions and aconversely, reduced capacitya cushioned to finance impactfuture of highpublic debt 7 in situations12ofincreased investment, very strong uncertainty institutions and catalyser (Masuch for 2016). et al., banking crisis.string A long 13 of research tends to conclude that high public debt can adversely affect growth through the channels of sovereign spreads (confidence The literature also points out 8 that the level is not the only relevant9 dimension in debt-related effects) and sovereign yields, financial intermediation (bank credit), higher future distortionary vulnerabilities. taxation,10 future Other characteristics crowding-out of privatedefining investmentits composition, 11 (debt is a like the maturity deadweight burden structure, financing on the economy), method and the resulting composition of public debt can also have sizable economic effects. 14 A greater lower scope for counter-cyclical fiscal policy, including a reduced capacity to finance future public share of short-term investment, 12 increased debt uncertainty may make aand government catalyser more vulnerable for banking crisis.during 13 a crisis, because of the need to roll over increased amounts of debt. Moreover, in case a debt crisis mixes elements of illiquidity and insolvency, The literature like also the euro pointsareaout sovereign that the crisis, level theisgovernment not the only would be vulnerable relevant dimension to badin news, whose debt-related real impact would vulnerabilities. be amplified Other by creditors’ characteristics defining unwillingness its composition, to roll over like thetheirmaturity claims. structure, financing method and the resulting composition of public debt can also have sizable economic effects.14 A greater In our ofpaper, share short-termwe use debtDSGE may makemodel simulations more a government to investigate vulnerable the two main during a crisis,aspects because related of thetoneedthe macroeconomic to roll over increased consequences amounts ofofdebt. high Moreover, public debtinemphasized case a debtby the mixes crisis literature: a reduced elements capacity of illiquidity of and high debt economies to withstand shocks and adverse effects on potential insolvency, like the euro area sovereign crisis, the government would be vulnerable to bad news, whose (long-term) output. In doing so, realwe coverwould impact topicsbe that belong to amplified byvarious creditors’strings of the literature: unwillingness to roll on oversovereign their claims.default and nonlinearities between debt and output (Corsetti et al., 2013; Bi and Leeper, 2010), on fiscal multipliers (Coenen et al., In our 2012), paper, fiscal we usespillovers DSGE (Alloza et al., 2019a, model simulations 2019b; Attinasi to investigate the twoetmain 2017; Auerbach al., aspects related to and the Gorodnichenko, macroeconomic consequences2012), or on the interaction of high public debt between fiscal and emphasized bymonetary the literature: policy, in particular a reduced capacity when of nominal high debtinterest economies ratestoare constrained withstand shocks by an andeffective adverselower effects bound (Bouakeza, on potential et al., 2017; (long-term) output. Bletzinger In doing and so, we Lalik, 2017; cover Arce topics et belong that al., 2016; Hills and to various Nakata, strings 2014). of the Compared literature: with these on sovereign papers, default andours assesses nonlinearities more between systematically debt and output the macroeconomic (Corsetti et al., implications 2013; Bi andofLeeper, high public 2010), debtoninfiscal a global DSGE(Coenen multipliers setup with et three different al., 2012), models fiscal designed spillovers for theeteuro (Alloza al.,area. 2019a, 2019b; Attinasi et al., 2017; Auerbach and Gorodnichenko, 2012), or on the interaction between fiscal and monetary policy, in particular when nominal interest rates are constrained by an effective lower bound (Bouakeza, et al., 2017; Bletzinger and 7 Lalik, Several 2017; studies empirical Arce et(spanning al., 2016; Hills and all major Nakata, institutions) find2014). Compared a negative, with these mostly nonlinear, papers, impact of publicours debtassesses on growth. Woo and Kumar (2015) find evidence of nonlinearity with higher levels of initial debt (above 90% of GDP) having more more systematically significantly the macroeconomic negative effects on subsequent growth. implications For the euroof areahigh public sample beforedebt in a global the crisis, DSGE Checherita setup(2012) and Rother with find an inverted U-shape relationship between three different models designed for the euro area. public debt and growth with a median debt threshold endogenously determined at 90-100% of GDP. Subsequent research for the euro area (Baum et al., 2012) investigates the short-run impact of public debt on GDP growth for a more recent period (1990-2010).The authors find a positive and highly statistically significant effect, which decreases however to around zero and loses significance beyond public debt-to-GDP ratios of around 67%. For high debt-to-GDP ratios (above 95%), additional debt is found to have a negative impact on economic activity. Similar debt 7 Several empirical thresholds studiesin(spanning are found the literatureall major institutions) on early signals offind a negative, sovereign mostlyFor distress. nonlinear, instance, impact of public the current debt debt on growth. sustainability Woo andframework analysis Kumar (2015) of the find IMF evidence (in placeof since nonlinearity with higher 2013) adopts levels a debt ratioofofinitial 85% debt of GDP(above 90% to flag of GDP) fiscal risks having more in advanced significantlyalong economies negativethis effects on subsequent growth. For the euro area sample before the crisis, Checherita and Rother (2012) dimension. find an inverted U-shape relationship between public debt and growth with a median debt threshold endogenously determined 8 Seeat Codogno 90-100% et of al. GDP.(2003), Attinasi et Subsequent al (2010) research forand theCorsetti euro area et al. (2013) (Baum et for al., the effect 2012) on spreads investigates theand Laubach short-run (2009), impact of Baum public et debtal.on (2012) GDPfor the effect growth on long-term for a more sovereign recent period interest rates.authors find a positive and highly statistically significant effect, (1990-2010).The 9 See De Bonis which and Stacchini decreases however(2013)to aroundfor the zeroimpact on bank and loses credit andbeyond significance Jorda etpublic al. (2016) for the effects debt-to-GDP ratiosinofthe aftermath around 67%.ofForcrises. high The latter paper debt-to-GDP explores ratios (abovea 95%), historical database additional on is debt public- foundand private-sector to have a negative debt build-ups impact for advanced on economic countries activity. Similarfordebt the period thresholds1870–2011 are found andinfinds the that although literature high public on early signalsdebt build-ups are of sovereign not correlated distress. with athe For instance, greater currentlikelihood of financial debt sustainability crisis, analysis a high level of of framework public debt (in the IMF does tendsince place to exacerbate 2013) adoptsthe negative effects a debt ratio of of post-crisis 85% of GDPfinancial sectorrisks to flag fiscal deleveraging. in advanced 10 Ineconomies along line with Barro this dimension. (1979). This can, in turn, affect precautionary savings and consumption today. 8 11See WooCodogno and Kumar et al. (2003), (2015), Attinasi Ostry et al.et(2015). al (2010) and Corsetti et al. (2013) for the effect on spreads and Laubach (2009), Baum et al. (2012) for the effect on long-term sovereign interest rates. 12 Chalk and Tanzi (2004), Checherita and Rother (2012). 9 See De Bonis and Stacchini (2013) for the impact on bank credit and Jorda et al. (2016) for the effects in the aftermath of crises. 13 See TheHemming et al.explores latter paper (2013); a Brunnermeier et al. (2016). historical database on public- and private-sector debt build-ups for advanced countries for the 14 See, for example, period 1870–2011 Bacchiocchi and finds that and although Missale (2005), Faraglia high public debtetbuild-ups al. (2008), areornotHatchondo correlated and Martínez with a greater(2013). likelihood of financial crisis, a high level of public debt does tend to exacerbate the negative effects of post-crisis financial sector deleveraging. 10 In line with Barro (1979). This can, in turn, affect precautionary savings and consumption today. BANCO DE ESPAÑA 11 DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N.º 2029 8 11 Woo and Kumar (2015), Ostry et al. (2015). 12 Chalk and Tanzi (2004), Checherita and Rother (2012). 13 See Hemming et al. (2013); Brunnermeier et al. (2016). 14 See, for example, Bacchiocchi and Missale (2005), Faraglia et al. (2008), or Hatchondo and Martínez (2013).
You can also read