The 2009 Report on Domestic Wood Fireplace Inserts: World Market Segmentation by City

Page created by Ann Wright
 
CONTINUE READING
Brochure
More information from http://www.researchandmarkets.com/reports/1030321/

The 2009 Report on Domestic Wood Fireplace Inserts: World Market
Segmentation by City

Description:     Market Potential Estimation Methodology
                 Overview
                 This study covers the world outlook for domestic wood fireplace inserts across more than 2000 cities. For
                 the year reported, estimates are given for the latent demand, or potential industry earnings (P.I.E.), for the
                 city in question (in millions of U.S. dollars), the percent share the city is of the region and of the globe. These
                 comparative benchmarks allow the reader to quickly gauge a city vis-à-vis others. Using econometric models
                 which project fundamental economic dynamics within each country and across countries, latent demand
                 estimates are created. This report does not discuss the specific players in the market serving the latent
                 demand, nor specific details at the product level. The study also does not consider short-term cyclicalities
                 that might affect realized sales. The study, therefore, is strategic in nature, taking an aggregate and long-run
                 view, irrespective of the players or products involved.

                 This study does not report actual sales data (which are simply unavailable, in a comparable or consistent
                 manner in virtually all of the cities of the world). This study gives, however, my estimates for the worldwide
                 latent demand, or the P.I.E. for domestic wood fireplace inserts. It also shows how the P.I.E. is divided across
                 the world’s cities. In order to make these estimates, a multi-stage methodology was employed that is often
                 taught in courses on international strategic planning at graduate schools of business.

                 What is Latent Demand and the P.I.E.?
                 The concept of latent demand is rather subtle. The term latent typically refers to something that is dormant,
                 not observable, or not yet realized. Demand is the notion of an economic quantity that a target population
                 or market requires under different assumptions of price, quality, and distribution, among other factors.
                 Latent demand, therefore, is commonly defined by economists as the industry earnings of a market when
                 that market becomes accessible and attractive to serve by competing firms. It is a measure, therefore, of
                 potential industry earnings (P.I.E.) or total revenues (not profit) if a market is served in an efficient manner. It
                 is typically expressed as the total revenues potentially extracted by firms. The “market” is defined at a given
                 level in the value chain. There can be latent demand at the retail level, at the wholesale level, the
                 manufacturing level, and the raw materials level (the P.I.E. of higher levels of the value chain being always
                 smaller than the P.I.E. of levels at lower levels of the same value chain, assuming all levels maintain
                 minimum profitability).

                 The latent demand for domestic wood fireplace inserts is not actual or historic sales. Nor is latent demand
                 future sales. In fact, latent demand can be lower either lower or higher than actual sales if a market is
                 inefficient (i.e., not representative of relatively competitive levels). Inefficiencies arise from a number of
                 factors, including the lack of international openness, cultural barriers to consumption, regulations, and
                 cartel-like behavior on the part of firms. In general, however, latent demand is typically larger than actual
                 sales in a city market.

                 Another reason why sales do not equate to latent demand is exchange rates. In this report, all figures
                 assume the long-run efficiency of currency markets. Figures, therefore, equate values based on purchasing
                 power parities across countries. Short-run distortions in the value of the dollar, therefore, do not figure into
                 the estimates. Purchasing power parity estimates of country income were collected from official sources,
                 and extrapolated using standard econometric models. The report uses the dollar as the currency of
                 comparison, but not as a measure of transaction volume. The units used in this report are: US $ mln.

                 For reasons discussed later, this report does not consider the notion of “unit quantities”, only total latent
                 revenues (i.e., a calculation of price times quantity is never made, though one is implied). The units used in
                 this report are U.S. dollars not adjusted for inflation (i.e., the figures incorporate inflationary trends) and not
                 adjusted for future dynamics in exchange rates (i.e., the figures reflect average exchange rates over recent
                 history). If inflation rates or exchange rates vary in a substantial way compared to recent experience,
                 actually sales can also exceed latent demand (when expressed in U.S. dollars, not adjusted for inflation). On
                 the other hand, latent demand can be typically higher than actual sales as there are often distribution
                 inefficiencies that reduce actual sales below the level of latent demand.
As mentioned earlier, this study is strategic in nature, taking an aggregate and long-run view, irrespective of
the players or products involved. If fact, all the current products or services on the market can cease to exist
in their present form (i.e., at a brand-, R&D specification, or corporate-image level) and all the players can be
replaced by other firms (i.e., via exits, entries, mergers, bankruptcies, etc.), and there will still be an
international latent demand for domestic wood fireplace inserts at the aggregate level. Product and service
offering details, and the actual identity of the players involved, while important for certain issues, are
relatively unimportant for estimates of latent demand.

The Methodology
In order to estimate the latent demand for domestic wood fireplace inserts on a city-by-city basis, I used a
multi-stage approach. Before applying the approach, one needs a basic theory from which such estimates
are created. In this case, I heavily rely on the use of certain basic economic assumptions. In particular, there
is an assumption governing the shape and type of aggregate latent demand functions. Latent demand
functions relate the income of a country, city, state, household, or individual to realized consumption. Latent
demand (often realized as consumption when an industry is efficient), at any level of the value chain, takes
place if an equilibrium in realized. For firms to serve a market, they must perceive a latent demand and be
able to serve that demand at a minimal return. The single most important variable determining
consumption, assuming latent demand exists, is income (or other financial resources at higher levels of the
value chain). Other factors that can pivot or shape demand curves include external or exogenous shocks
(i.e., business cycles), and or changes in utility for the product in question.

Ignoring, for the moment, exogenous shocks and variations in utility across countries, the aggregate relation
between income and consumption has been a central theme in economics. The figure below concisely
summarizes one aspect of problem. In the 1930s, John Meynard Keynes conjectured that as incomes rise,
the average propensity to consume would fall. The average propensity to consume is the level of
consumption divided by the level of income, or the slope of the line from the origin to the consumption
function. He estimated this relationship empirically and found it to be true in the short-run (mostly based on
cross-sectional data). The higher the income, the lower the average propensity to consume. This type of
consumption function is labeled "A" in the figure below (note the rather flat slope of the curve). In the 1940s,
another macroeconomist, Simon Kuznets, estimated long-run consumption functions which indicated that
the marginal propensity to consume was rather constant (using time series data across countries). This type
of consumption function is show as "B" in the figure below (note the higher slope and zero-zero intercept).
The average propensity to consume is constant.

Is it declining or is it constant? A number of other economists, notably Franco Modigliani and Milton
Friedman, in the 1950s (and Irving Fisher earlier), explained why the two functions were different using
various assumptions on intertemporal budget constraints, savings, and wealth. The shorter the time
horizon, the more consumption can depend on wealth (earned in previous years) and business cycles. In the
long-run, however, the propensity to consume is more constant. Similarly, in the long run, households,
industries or countries with no income eventually have no consumption (wealth is depleted). While the
debate surrounding beliefs about how income and consumption are related and interesting, in this study a
very particular school of thought is adopted. In particular, we are considering the latent demand for
domestic wood fireplace inserts across some 230 countries. The smallest have fewer than 10,000
inhabitants. I assume that all of these counties fall along a "long-run" aggregate consumption function. This
long-run function applies despite some of these countries having wealth, current income dominates the
latent demand for domestic wood fireplace inserts. So, latent demand in the long-run has a zero intercept.
However, I allow firms to have different propensities to consume (including being on consumption functions
with differing slopes, which can account for differences in industrial organization, and end-user
preferences).

Given this overriding philosophy, I will now describe the methodology used to create the latent demand
estimates for domestic wood fireplace inserts. Since ICON Group has asked me to apply this methodology to
a large number of categories, the rather academic discussion below is general and can be applied to a wide
variety of categories, not just domestic wood fireplace inserts.

Step 1. Product Definition and Data Collection
Any study of latent demand across countries requires that some standard be established to define
“efficiently served”. Having implemented various alternatives and matched these with market outcomes, I
have found that the optimal approach is to assume that certain key countries or cities are more likely to be
at or near efficiency than others. These are given greater weight than others in the estimation of latent
demand compared to others for which no known data are available. Of the many alternatives, I have found
the assumption that the world’s highest aggregate income and highest income-per-capita markets reflect
the best standards for “efficiency”. High aggregate income alone is not sufficient (i.e., China has high
aggregate income, but low income per capita and can not assumed to be efficient). Aggregate income can be
operationalized in a number of ways, including gross domestic product (for industrial categories), or total
disposable income (for household categories; population times average income per capita, or number of
households times average household income per capita). Brunei, Nauru, Kuwait, and Lichtenstein are
examples of countries with high income per capita, but not assumed to be efficient, given low aggregate
level of income (or gross domestic product); these countries have, however, high incomes per capita but
may not benefit from the efficiencies derived from economies of scale associated with large economies.
Only countries with high income per capita and large aggregate income are assumed efficient. This greatly
restricts the pool of countries to those in the OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development), like the United States, or the United Kingdom (which were earlier than other large OECD
economies to liberalize their markets).

The selection of countries is further reduced by the fact that not all countries in the OECD report industry
revenues at the category level. Countries that typically have ample data at the aggregate level that meet the
efficiency criteria include the United States, the United Kingdom and in some cases France and Germany.

Latent demand is therefore estimated using data collected for relatively efficient markets from independent
data sources (e.g. Euromonitor, Mintel, Thomson Financial Services, the U.S. Industrial Outlook, the World
Resources Institute, the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, various agencies from
the United Nations, industry trade associations, the International Monetary Fund, and the World Bank).
Depending on original data sources used, the definition of “domestic wood fireplace inserts” is established.
In the case of this report, the data were reported at the aggregate level, with no further breakdown or
definition. In other words, any potential product or service that might be incorporated within domestic wood
fireplace inserts falls under this category. Public sources rarely report data at the disaggregated level in
order to protect private information from individual firms that might dominate a specific product-market.
These sources will therefore aggregate across components of a category and report only the aggregate to
the public. While private data are certainly available, this report only relies on public data at the aggregate
level without reliance on the summation of various category components. In other words, this report does
not aggregate a number of components to arrive at the “whole”. Rather, it starts with the “whole”, and
estimates the whole for all cities and the world at large (without needing to know the specific parts that went
into the whole in the first place).

Given this caveat, this study covers “domestic wood fireplace inserts” as defined by the North American
Industrial Classification system or NAICS (pronounced “nakes”). For a complete definition of domestic wood
fireplace inserts, please refer to the Web site at http://www.icongrouponline.com/codes/NAICS.html. The
NAICS code for domestic wood fireplace inserts is 3334143151. It is for this definition of domestic wood
fireplace inserts that the aggregate latent demand estimates are derived. “Domestic wood fireplace inserts”
is specifically defined as follows:

3334143151
Domestic wood fireplace inserts
Step 2. Filtering and Smoothing
            Based on the aggregate view of domestic wood fireplace inserts as defined above, data were then collected
            for as many similar countries and cities as possible for that same definition, at the same level of the value
            chain. This generates a convenience sample from which comparable figures are available. If the series in
            question do not reflect the same accounting period, then adjustments are made. In order to eliminate short-
            term effects of business cycles, the series are smoothed using an 2 year moving average weighting scheme
            (longer weighting schemes do not substantially change the results). If data are available for a country, but
            these reflect short-run aberrations due to exogenous shocks (such as would be the case of beef sales in a
            country stricken with foot and mouth disease), these observations were dropped or "filtered" from the
            analysis.

            Step 3. Filling in Missing Values
            In some cases, data are available for countries or cities on a sporadic basis. In other cases, data may be
            available for only one year. From a Bayesian perspective, these observations should be given greatest
            weight in estimating missing years. Assuming that other factors are held constant, the missing years are
            extrapolated using changes and growth in aggregate national income. Based on the overriding philosophy of
            a long-run consumption function (defined earlier), cities which have missing data for any given year, are
            estimated based on historical dynamics of aggregate income for that country.

            Step 4. Varying Parameter, Non-linear Estimation
            Given the data available from the first three steps, the latent demand is estimated using a “varying-
            parameter cross-sectionally pooled time series model”. Simply stated, the effect of income on latent demand
            is assumed to be constant across cities unless there is empirical evidence to suggest that this effect varies
            (i.e., the slope of the income effect is not necessarily same for all countries). This assumption applies across
            cities along the aggregate consumption function, but also over time (i.e., not all cities are perceived to have
            the same income growth prospects over time and this effect can vary from city to city as well). Another way
            of looking at this is to say that latent demand for domestic wood fireplace inserts is more likely to be similar
            across cities that have similar characteristics in terms of economic development (i.e., African cities will have
            similar latent demand structures controlling for the income variation across the pool of African cities).

            This approach is useful across cities for which some notion of non-linearity exists in the aggregate
            consumption function. For some categories, however, the reader must realize that the numbers will reflect a
            city’s contribution to global latent demand and may never be realized in the form of local sales. For certain
            category combinations this will result in what at first glance will be odd results. For example, the latent
            demand for the category “space vehicles” will exist for cities in “Togo” even though they have no space
            program. The assumption is that if the economies in these countries did not exist, the world aggregate for
            these categories would be lower. The share attributed to these cities is based on a proportion of their
            income (however small) being used to consume the category in question (i.e., perhaps via resellers).

            Step 5. Fixed-Parameter Linear Estimation
            Nonlinearities are assumed in cases where filtered data exist along the aggregate consumption function.
            Because the world consists of more than 2000 cities, there will always be those cities, especially toward the
            bottom of the consumption function, where non-linear estimation is simply not possible. For these cities,
            equilibrium latent demand is assumed to be perfectly parametric and not a function of wealth (i.e., a city’s
            stock of income), but a function of current income (a city’s flow of income). In the long run, if a city has no
            current income, the latent demand for domestic wood fireplace inserts is assumed to approach zero. The
            assumption is that wealth stocks fall rapidly to zero if flow income falls to zero (i.e., cities which earn low
            levels of income will not use their savings, in the long run, to demand domestic wood fireplace inserts). In a
            graphical sense, for low income cities, latent demand approaches zero in a parametric linear fashion with a
            zero-zero intercept. In this stage of the estimation procedure, low-income cities are assumed to have a
            latent demand proportional to their income, based on the city closest to it on the aggregate consumption
            function.

            Step 6. Aggregation and Benchmarking
            Based on the models described above, latent demand figures are estimated for all cities of the world,
            including for the smallest economies. These are then aggregated to get world totals and regional totals. To
            make the numbers more meaningful, regional and global demand averages are presented. Figures are
            rounded, so minor inconsistencies may exist across tables.

Contents:   1 INTRODUCTION & METHODOLOGY 11
            1.1 Overview and Definitions 11
1.2 Market Potential Estimation Methodology 11
1.2.1 Overview 11
1.2.2 What is Latent Demand and the P.I.E.? 12
1.2.3 The Methodology 12
1.2.3.1 Step 1. Product Definition and Data Collection 14
1.2.3.2 Step 2. Filtering and Smoothing 15
1.2.3.3 Step 3. Filling in Missing Values 15
1.2.3.4 Step 4. Varying Parameter, Non-linear Estimation 15
1.2.3.5 Step 5. Fixed-Parameter Linear Estimation 16
1.2.3.6 Step 6. Aggregation and Benchmarking 16
2 USING THE DATA 17
3 CITY SEGMENTS RANKED BY MARKET SIZE 18
3.1 Top 15 Markets 18
3.2 Markets 16 to 30 19
3.3 Remaining Cities by Market Rank 20
4 CITY SEGMENTS IN ALPHABETICAL ORDER 123
4.1 A: from Aalborg to Az Zawiyah 123
4.2 B: from Bacolod to Bydgoszcz 130
4.3 C: from Caaguazu to Cyangugu 138
4.4 D: from Da Nang to Dzhizak 146
4.5 E: from East London to Esteli 150
4.6 F: from Fagatogo to Funchal 152
4.7 G: from Gabes to Gyumri 155
4.8 H: from Hachinohe to Hyderabad 159
4.9 I: from Iasi to Izmir 163
4.10 J: from Jaboatao to Jyvaskyla 166
4.11 K: from Kabul to Kzyl-Orda 168
4.12 L: from La Ceiba to Lyon 176
4.13 M: from Macae to Mzuzu 181
4.14 N: from Nacala to Nzerekore 191
4.15 O: from Oaklahoma City to Oyem 196
4.16 Ö: from Örebro to Örebro 198
4.17 P: from Pago Pago to Pyuthan 199
4.18 Q: from Qandahar to Quito 205
4.19 R: from Rabat to Rustavi 206
4.20 S: from S. Luis Potosi to Szombathely 209
4.21 T: from Tabligbo to Tyre 221
4.22 U: from Uberaba to Utulei 228
4.23 V: from Vacoas-Phoenix to Vukovar 230
4.24 W: from Wadi Medani to Wuhan 233
4.25 X: from Xalapa to Xian 234
4.26 Y: from Yamagata to Yungkang 235
4.27 Z: from Zadar to Zvishavane 236
5 CITY SEGMENTS RANKED BY COUNTRY 237
5.1 Afghanistan 237
5.2 Albania 237
5.3 Algeria 238
5.4 American Samoa 238
5.5 Andorra 238
5.6 Angola 239
5.7 Antigua and Barbuda 239
5.8 Argentina 240
5.9 Armenia 241
5.10 Aruba 241
5.11 Australia 242
5.12 Austria 242
5.13 Azerbaijan 243
5.14 Bahrain 243
5.15 Bangladesh 243
5.16 Barbados 244
5.17 Belarus 244
5.18 Belgium 244
5.19 Belize 245
5.20 Benin 245
5.21 Bermuda 245
5.22 Bhutan 246
5.23 Bolivia 246
5.24 Bosnia and Herzegovina 246
5.25 Botswana 247
5.26 Brazil 248
5.27 Brunei 253
5.28 Bulgaria 253
5.29 Burkina Faso 254
5.30 Burma 254
5.31 Burundi 254
5.32 Cambodia 255
5.33 Cameroon 255
5.34 Canada 255
5.35 Cape Verde 256
5.36 Central African Republic 256
5.37 Chad 256
5.38 Chile 257
5.39 China 257
5.40 Christmas Island 258
5.41 Colombia 258
5.42 Comoros 258
5.43 Congo (formerly Zaire) 259
5.44 Cook Islands 259
5.45 Costa Rica 259
5.46 Cote dIvoire 260
5.47 Croatia 260
5.48 Cuba 260
5.49 Cyprus 261
5.50 Czech Republic 261
5.51 Denmark 261
5.52 Djibouti 262
5.53 Dominica 262
5.54 Dominican Republic 262
5.55 Ecuador 263
5.56 Egypt 263
5.57 El Salvador 263
5.58 Equatorial Guinea 264
5.59 Estonia 264
5.60 Ethiopia 264
5.61 Fiji 265
5.62 Finland 265
5.63 France 266
5.64 French Guiana 266
5.65 French Polynesia 267
5.66 Gabon 267
5.67 Georgia 267
5.68 Germany 268
5.69 Ghana 268
5.70 Greece 269
5.71 Greenland 269
5.72 Grenada 269
5.73 Guadeloupe 270
5.74 Guam 270
5.75 Guatemala 270
5.76 Guinea 271
5.77 Guinea-Bissau 271
5.78 Guyana 271
5.79 Haiti 272
5.80 Honduras 272
5.81 Hong Kong 272
5.82 Hungary 273
5.83 Iceland 273
5.84 India 274
5.85 Indonesia 275
5.86 Iran 276
5.87 Iraq 276
5.88 Ireland 277
5.89 Israel 277
5.90 Italy 278
5.91 Jamaica 278
5.92 Japan 279
5.93 Jordan 281
5.94 Kazakhstan 282
5.95 Kenya 282
5.96 Kiribati 283
5.97 Kuwait 283
5.98 Kyrgyzstan 283
5.99 Laos 283
5.100 Latvia 284
5.101 Lebanon 284
5.102 Lesotho 284
5.103 Liberia 285
5.104 Libya 285
5.105 Liechtenstein 285
5.106 Lithuania 286
5.107 Luxembourg 286
5.108 Macau 286
5.109 Madagascar 287
5.110 Malawi 287
5.111 Malaysia 288
5.112 Maldives 288
5.113 Mali 289
5.114 Malta 289
5.115 Marshall Islands 289
5.116 Martinique 290
5.117 Mauritania 290
5.118 Mauritius 290
5.119 Mexico 291
5.120 Micronesia Federation 292
5.121 Moldova 292
5.122 Monaco 292
5.123 Mongolia 292
5.124 Morocco 293
5.125 Mozambique 293
5.126 Namibia 293
5.127 Nauru 294
5.128 Nepal 294
5.129 New Caledonia 294
5.130 New Zealand 295
5.131 Nicaragua 295
5.132 Niger 296
5.133 Nigeria 296
5.134 Niue 296
5.135 Norfolk Island 297
5.136 North Korea 297
5.137 Norway 297
5.138 Oman 298
5.139 Pakistan 298
5.140 Palau 298
5.141 Palestine 298
5.142 Panama 299
5.143 Papua New Guinea 299
5.144 Paraguay 299
5.145 Peru 300
5.146 Philippines 300
5.147 Poland 301
5.148 Portugal 301
5.149 Puerto Rico 302
5.150 Qatar 302
5.151 Republic of Congo 302
5.152 Reunion 303
5.153 Romania 303
5.154 Russia 304
5.155 Rwanda 304
5.156 San Marino 304
5.157 Sao Tome E Principe 305
5.158 Saudi Arabia 305
5.159 Senegal 305
5.160 Seychelles 306
5.161 Sierra Leone 306
5.162 Singapore 306
5.163 Slovakia 306
5.164 Slovenia 307
5.165 Solomon Islands 307
5.166 Somalia 307
5.167 South Africa 308
5.168 South Korea 308
5.169 Spain 309
5.170 Sri Lanka 309
5.171 St. Kitts and Nevis 310
5.172 St. Lucia 310
5.173 St. Vincent and the Grenadines 310
5.174 Sudan 310
5.175 Suriname 311
5.176 Swaziland 311
5.177 Sweden 311
5.178 Switzerland 312
5.179 Syrian Arab Republic 312
5.180 Taiwan 313
5.181 Tajikistan 314
5.182 Tanzania 314
5.183 Thailand 314
5.184 The Bahamas 315
5.185 The British Virgin Islands 315
5.186 The Cayman Islands 315
5.187 The Falkland Islands 315
5.188 The Gambia 316
5.189 The Netherlands 316
5.190 The Netherlands Antilles 316
5.191 The Northern Mariana Island 317
5.192 The U.S. Virgin Islands 317
5.193 The United Arab Emirates 317
5.194 The United Kingdom 318
5.195 The United States 319
5.196 Togo 320
5.197 Tokelau 320
5.198 Tonga 320
5.199 Trinidad and Tobago 321
5.200 Tunisia 321
5.201 Turkey 322
5.202 Turkmenistan 322
5.203 Tuvalu 322
5.204 Uganda 323
5.205 Ukraine 323
5.206 Uruguay 324
5.207 Uzbekistan 324
5.208 Vanuatu 324
5.209 Venezuela 325
            5.210 Vietnam 325
            5.211 Wallis and Futuna 326
            5.212 Western Sahara 326
            5.213 Western Samoa 326
            5.214 Yemen 326
            5.215 Zambia 327
            5.216 Zimbabwe 327
            6 DISCLAIMERS, WARRANTEES, AND USER AGREEMENT PROVISIONS 328
            6.1 Disclaimers & Safe Harbor 328
            6.2 ICON Group International, Inc. User Agreement Provisions 329

Ordering:   Order Online - http://www.researchandmarkets.com/reports/1030321/

            Order by Fax - using the form below

            Order by Post - print the order form below and send to

                      Research and Markets,
                      Guinness Centre,
                      Taylors Lane,
                      Dublin 8,
                      Ireland.
Page 1 of 2

Fax Order Form
To place an order via fax simply print this form, fill in the information below and fax the completed form to 646-607-1907 (from
USA) or +353-1-481-1716 (from Rest of World). If you have any questions please visit

http://www.researchandmarkets.com/contact/

Order Information
Please verify that the product information is correct.

                   Product Name:             The 2009 Report on Domestic Wood Fireplace Inserts: World Market Segmentation
                                             by City
                   Web Address:              http://www.researchandmarkets.com/reports/1030321/
                   Office Code:              SC3X1UC7

Product Format
Please select the product format and quantity you require:

                                        Quantity
                   Electronic (PDF) -
                                               USD 795
                   Single User:

Contact Information
Please enter all the information below in BLOCK CAPITALS

      Title:                      Mr               Mrs            Dr           Miss               Ms          Prof

      First Name:                                                          Last Name:

      Email Address: *

      Job Title:

      Organisation:

      Address:

      City:

      Postal / Zip Code:

      Country:

      Phone Number:

      Fax Number:

      * Please refrain from using free email accounts when ordering (e.g. Yahoo, Hotmail, AOL)
Page 2 of 2

Payment Information
Please indicate the payment method you would like to use by selecting the appropriate box.

                                              You will receive an email with a link to a secure webpage to enter your
           Pay by credit card:                credit card details.

           Pay by check:                      Please post the check, accompanied by this form, to:

                                              Research and Markets,
                                              Guinness Center,
                                              Taylors Lane,
                                              Dublin 8,
                                              Ireland.

                                              Please transfer funds to:
           Pay by wire transfer:
                                              Account number                  833 130 83
                                              Sort code                       98-53-30
                                              Swift code                      ULSBIE2D
                                              IBAN number                     IE78ULSB98533083313083
                                              Bank Address                 Ulster Bank,
                                                                           27-35 Main Street,
                                                                           Blackrock,
                                                                           Co. Dublin,
                                                                           Ireland.

      If you have a Marketing Code please enter it below:

            Marketing Code:

      Please note that by ordering from Research and Markets you are agreeing to our Terms and Conditions at
      http://www.researchandmarkets.com/info/terms.asp

                                                   Please fax this form to:
                                       (646) 607-1907 or (646) 964-6609 - From USA
                                 +353-1-481-1716 or +353-1-653-1571 - From Rest of World
You can also read